The WTO and the Shrinking of Development Space

How Big is the Bite?

in The Journal of World Investment & Trade
Restricted Access
Get Access to Full Text
Rent on DeepDyve

Have an Access Token?



Enter your access token to activate and access content online.

Please login and go to your personal user account to enter your access token.



Help

Have Institutional Access?



Access content through your institution. Any other coaching guidance?



Connect

The WTO and the Shrinking of Development Space

How Big is the Bite?

in The Journal of World Investment & Trade

References

The single set of Nics we examine includes Brazil, Mexico, India, South Korea, Hong Kong and Taiwan. This list is a simplified group of both first- and second-tier Nics, using an adapted definition based on the criteria used in the East Asian Miracle Report (World Bank, 1993). The first tier is defined as the 4 tigers, which are all are commonly classified as high-performing Asian economies. This tier includes South Korea, Hong Kong, Taiwan, and Singapore. The East Asian Miracle Report describes the second tier as "newly industrializing economies". While the Report deals only with Asia, we use their criteria to also include countries such as Brazil and Mexico, since they also fall into the top 20 growth group, the same as the second-tier Asian countries. Second-tier countries can thus be defined to include Brazil, Mexico, India, Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand. So, together, the group of first- and second-tier developing countries become the single set of Nics considered in this article.

2 These policies were not exclusive to the Nics; similar policies and activities were also used by the First World countries (Chang, 2004). 3 There are a number of rules-based analyses documenting various facets of this occurrence. See, for example, Wade (2003); Shadlcn (2005); see also Amsden (2005). 4 The Trade Policy Reviews that we read through include: Brazil (1992, 1996, 2000, 2004); India (1993, 1998, 2002); Indonesia (1990, 1994, 1998, 2003); Malaysia (1993, 1997, 2001); Mexico (1993, 1997, 2002); South Korea (1996, 2000, 2004); and Thailand (1991, 1995, 1999, 2003).

As Amsden (2001) notes in her discussion of "getting the prices wrong", the open market pricing system is not necessarily an efficient coordinating mechanism. Under perfect markets, prices reflect scarcity, which serves to incentivize production. However, in a world where profits in many sectors are tied to proprietary knowledge, prices provide inadequate indicators. This problem was recognized early on by Gershenkron (1962), who suggested that more than a market signal would be necessary in order to stimulate investment in non-traditional markets.

6 There are also a number of other sources that contribute to the shrinking policy space available to countries: mission creep in aid agencies; and free trade agreements. For a historical perspective, see Chang, 2005. In this paper, we focus exclusively on the WTO.

For a survey of the various studies on the different rates of social and private returns, see Hall, 1996.

I In the case that pre-dated and foreshadowed the Agrcement on Trade-Related Investment Measures, the Panel ruled Canada could not give differential treatment to Canadian firms. Because a group of developing countries threatened to block the Panel decision, the 1984 settlement includes a paragraph at the end that the interpretation would not apply to the developing countries: "The Panel recognizes that in disputes involving less-developed contracting parties, full account should be taken of the special provisions in the General Agreement relating to these countries." Panel Report, GATT FiRn Case, 7 February 1984, 5(a) 5.2.

9 Article 9(1): "Signatories shall not grant export subsidies on products other than certain primary products." 10 Article 11(1): "Signatories recognize that subsidies other than export subsidies are widely used as important instruments for the promotion of social and economic policy objectives, and do not intend to restrict the right of signatories to use such subsidies ..."

Since production subsidies are a more efficient instrument than tariffs to increase production (for example, see Aiello, 2002).

12 The World Bank (2001) noted that the average tarifFrate on manufactured goods had fallen from 40 per cent to less than 5 per cent in 2001.

1' Interestingly, there were several requests for consultations against Brazil during 1996 and 1997, but none ever went beyond the consultation stage. 1; WT/DS59/R.

The developing countries generally had to implement reforms that were already in place in the advanced countries; see, for example, Finger and Schuler (2000).

�� One issue we do not discuss here is compensation-based shifting. The WTO sets down policy regulations but also enables countries to violate those regulations if they provide compensation to countries that are negatively affected by the violation. This type of shift is known as compensatory shifting. The State is not claiming that the policy has been withdrawn or has not explicitly moved it to a W ro-sanctioned exception, but, rather, the State is accepting that it needs to have tins policy and is willing to provide compensation in order to maintain it (Weiss, 2005). �� Brazil, July 1995: WT/Bop/N/4; India, July 1996, WT/Bop/N/11.

t8 Indonesia Trims Notification (23 May 1995), G/TRIMS/N/1/IDN/1. See, for example, Import Licensing Committee, Meeting of 5 May 2004 and Meeting of 15 June 2005.

20 Bora and Lloyd (1999) take the opinion that loopholes that are available to the developing countries arc also available to the industrial countries and so they do not provide an advantage.

Francesco Aiello, 2002: Ranking Production Subsidies and Import Tariffs under Different Scenarios, Journal of Applied Economic Letters, Vol. 9(11).

Alice Amsdcn, 1989: Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization.

Idem, 1997: Bringing Production Back In—Understanding Government's Economic Role in Late Industrialization, World Development, Vol. 25, p. 469.

Idem, 2001: The Rise of "The Rest": Challenges to the West from Late-Industrializing Economies.

Idem, 2005: Promoting Industry Under WTO Law, in Gallagher (ed.), op. cit.

Kyle Bagwell and Robert Staiger, 2004: Subsidy Agreements, NBER Working Paper No. 10292. Behrman and Srinivasan (eds.), 1995: Handbook of Development Economics.

R. Belderbos, A. Jie, C. Joen and L. Sleuwaegen, 2002: Local content requirements, vertical cooperation, and foreign direct investment, De Economist, Vol. 150(2).

Jagdish Bhagwati, 1988: Protectionism.

Bora and Lloyd, 1999: "Industrial policy and the WTO" conference, p. 19.

James Brander and Barbara Spencer, 1985: Export Subsidies and International Market Share Rivalry, Journal of International Economics Vol.18(1/2).

Thomas Brewer (ed.), 1996: Trade and Investment Policy, Vol. 11.

Thomas Brewer and Stephen Young, 1996: Investment Policies in Multilateral and Regional Agreements: A Comparative Analysis, in Brewer (cd.), op. cit.

A. Brown and R. Stern, 2006: Global Market Integration and National Sovereignty, World Economy, Vol. 29(3).

M. Butler and H. Hauser, 2000: The WTO dispute settlement system: a first assessment from an economic perspective, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, Vol. 16, p. 503.

Alfred Chandler, 1990: Scale and Scope: the Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism.

Ha-Joon Chang, 2002: Kicking Away the Ladder, London: Anthem Press.

Idem, 2004: The Regulation of Foreign Investment in Historical Perspective, European Journal of Development Research, Vol. 16(3).

Idem, 2005: Kicking Away the Ladder: Good Policies and Good Institutions in Historical Perspective, in Gallagher (ed.), op. cit.

Shubham Chaudhuri, Pinelopi Goldberg and Panle Jia, 2003: Estimating the Effects of Global Patent Protection in Pharmaceuticals: A Case Study of Quinolones in India, NBER Working Paper No. 10159.

Chenery and Srinivasan (eds.), 1989: The Handbook of Development Economics.

Judith Chin and Gene Grossman, 1988: Intellectual Property Rights and North-South Trade, NBER Working Paper No. 2769.

Chin and Ito, 2005: What Matters for Financial Development, NBER Working Paper No. 11370.

Chorev, 2005: The Institutional Project of Neo-liberal Globalism: The Case of the WTO, Theory and Society, Vol. 34, p. 317.

David Collie, 2000: A Rationale for the WTO Prohibition of Export Subsidies: Strategic Export Subsidies and World Welfare, Open Economies Review. Vol. 11, p. 229.

Ronald Davies and Christopher Ellis, 2001: Competition in Taxes and Performance Requirements for Foreign Direct Investment, University of Oregon Economics Department Working Papers.

Florencio DeSilanes, James Markusen and Thomas Rutherford, 1993: Anti-competitive and Rent Shifting Aspects of Domestic Content Provisions in Regional Trade Blocks, NBER Working Paper 4512.

Sebastian Edwards, 1989: On the Sequencing of Structural Reforms, NBER Working Paper No. 3138.

Evanson and Westfal, 1995: Technological Change and Technology Strategy, in Behrman and Srinivasan (eds.), op. cit.

Susan Feinberg and Sumit Majumdar, 2001: Technology Spillovers from Foreign Direct Investment in the Indian Pharmaceutical Industry, Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 32(3), p. 421.

J. Finger and P. Schuler, 2000: Implementation of Uruguay Round Commitments: The Development Challenge, World Economy, Vol. 23, p. 511.

Kevin P. Gallagher (ed.), 2005: Putting Development First: The Importance of Policy Space in the WTO and IFIS, London: Zed Books.

Ralph Gaumory and William Baumol, 2000: Global Trade and Conflicting National Interests.

Gereffi and Wyman (eds.), 1990: Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia.

Alexander Gershenkron, 1962: Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective.

Gene Grossman, 1981: The Theory of Domestic Content Protection and Content Preference, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 96(4).

Gene Grossman and Elhanan Helpman, 1991: Quality Ladders in the Theory of Growth, The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 58(1).

Idem, 1994: Protection for Sale, American Economic Review, Vol. 84, p. 833.

Bronwyn Hall, 1996: The Private and Social Returns to Research and Development, in Smith and Barfield (eds.), op. cit.

R. Haussman and D. Rodrik, 2003: Economic Development as Self-discovery, Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 72(2).

Hoekman, Mattoo and English (eds.), 2002: Development, Trade and the WTO: A Handbook.

Robert Hudec, 1987: Developing Countries in the GATT Legal System.

Idem, 1999: The new WTO dispute settlement procedure: an overview of the first three years, Minnesota Journal of Global Trade, Vol 8(1), p. 27.

Idem, 2002: The Adequacy of WTO Dispute Settlement Remedies: A Developing Country Perspective, in Hoekman, Mattoo and English (eds.), op. cit.

John Jackson, 1990: Restructuring the GATT System.

Idem, 1997: The World Trading System.

Keck and Low, 2004: Special and Differential Treatment in the WTO: Why When and How? Economic Research and Statistics Division, WTO Working Paper No. ERSD-2004-03.

Wolfgang Keller, 2004: International Technology Diffusion, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 42(3).

Tor Jakob Klette, Jarle Moen and Zvi Griliches, 2000: Do subsidies to commercial R&D reduce market failures? Microeconometric evaluation studies, Research Policy, Vol. 29(4,5).

Anne Krueger, 1990: Government Failures in Development, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 4(3), p. 9.

Nagesh Kumar, 1998: Multinational Enterprises, Regional Economic Integration and Export-Platform Production in the Host Countries: An Empirical Analysis for the US and Japanese Corporations, Weltwirschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 134, 450.

Lall and Theubal, 1998: 'Market-Stimulating' Technology Policies in Developing Countries: A Framework with Examples from East Asia, World Development, Vol. 26(8).

Little, Scitovsky and Scott, 1970: Industry and Trade in Some Developing Countries: A Comparative Study. G. Maggi, 1996: Strategic Trade Policies with Endogenous Mode of Competition, American Economic Review, Vol. 48.

Markusen, 1998: Contracts, Intellectual Property Rights, and Multinational Investment in Developing Countries, NBER Working Paper No. 6448.

H. Pack, 1989: Industrialization and Trade, in Chenery and Srinivasan (eds.), op. cit., p. 334.

Garry Purcell, 2001: Australia's Experience with Local Content Programs in the Auto Industry: Lessons for India and other Developing Countries, Journal of World Trade, Vol. 35, No. 2.

Marla Ripoll, 2005: Trade liberalization and the skill premium in developing economies, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 52(3).

Ris, 2004: World Trade and Development Report 2003: Cancun and Beyond, p. 30.

Dani Rodrik, 1987: Policy Targeting with Endogenous Distortions: Theory of Optimum Subsidy, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 102(4).

Idem, 2004: Industrial Policy for the 21st Century, K.S.G.

Santos-Paulino and Thirlwall, 2004: The Impact of Trade Liberalization on Exports, Imports and the Balance of Payments of Developing Countries, The Economic Journal, Vol. 114, p. f50.

T. Schultz, 1988: Educational Investment and Returns, in Chenery and Srinivasan (eds.), op. cit., Vol. 1.

Kenneth C. Shadlen, 2005: Exchanging Development for Market Access? Deep Integration and Industrial Policy under Multilateral and Regional-Bilateral Trade Agreements, Review of International Political Economy, Vol. 12(5).

Helena Shapiro, 1993: Automobiles: From Import Substitution to Export Promotion in Brazil and Mexico, in Yoffie (ed.), op. cit.

Helen Shapiro and Lance Taylor, 1990: The State and Industrial Strategy, World Development, Vol. 18, p. 861.

Ajit Singh, 1994: Openness and the Market Friendly Approach to Development: Learning the Right Lessons from Experience, World Development, Vol. 22(12).

Idem, 1996: The post-Uruguay Round World Trading System, Industrialization, Trade and Devlopment: Implications for the Asia-Pacific Developing Countries, in UNCTAD, op. cit.

Smith and Barfield (eds.), 1996: Technology, R&D and the Economy, Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution.

J. Stiglitz, 1989: Markets, Market Failures and Development, American Economic Review, Vol. 79(2).

M. Syrquin, 1989: Patterns of Structural Change, in Chenery and Srinivasan (eds.), op. cit., p. 245.

Hanns Ullrich, 2004: Expansionist Intellectual Property Protection and Reductionist Competition Rules: A TRIPS Perspective, Journal of International Economic Law, Vol. 7(2).

UNCTAD (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development), 1996: The Expansion of Trading Opportunities to the Year 2000 for Asia Pacific Developing Countries: Implications of the Uruguay Round and Adoption of Export Strategies.

Robert Wade, 1990a: Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government Intervention in East Asian Industrialization.

Idem, 1990b: Industrial Policy in East Asia: Does it Lead or Follow the Market, in Gereffi and Wyman (eds.), op. cit., p. 231.

Idem, 2003: What strategies are viable for developing countries today? The WTO and the Shrinking of 'development space', Review of International Political Economy, Vol. 10(4), p. 607.

L. Weiss, 2005: Global Governance, National Strategies: How Industrialized States Make Room to Move Under the WTO, Review of International Political Economy, Vol. 12(5).

World Bank, 1993: The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy, Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

Idem, 2001: Trade Blocs, Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

David Yoffie (ed.), 1993: Beyond Free Trade Firms Governments and Global Competition, Boston: HBS Press.

Index Card

Content Metrics

Content Metrics

All Time Past Year Past 30 Days
Abstract Views 18 18 12
Full Text Views 6 6 6
PDF Downloads 0 0 0
EPUB Downloads 0 0 0