Chapter 4 Commodity-Chained Peasants

Construction of the Philippine Food Extractive Enclave

In: Where Shrimp Eat Better than People
Authors:
Wilma A. Dunaway
Search for other papers by Wilma A. Dunaway in
Current site
Google Scholar
PubMed
Close
and
Maria Cecilia Macabuac
Search for other papers by Maria Cecilia Macabuac in
Current site
Google Scholar
PubMed
Close

Abstract

We investigate what has happened to the communities and the peasants of an Asian fishery in the wake of debt-driven development strategies. Since the early 1980s, Philippine policymakers have advocated an “agribusiness approach to countryside development” that prioritizes larger enterprises, fewer independent peasants and production of a limited array of export crops and fishery products (Republic of Philippines 2000). As a result, the ecological resources and peasant laborers of fisheries have been integrated into the global food system. We examine the commodity chains for shellfish, finfish and live reef species, through which regional brokers and commission merchants orchestrate the transfer of exports to national and global wholesalers and processors. Regional re-orientation of productive assets to prioritize exports has had four significant impacts on peasant communities: depeasantization, ecological degradation, loss of livelihood, and food insecurity.

Mindanao is the virgin resource paradise of the Philippines.

(InvestMindanao Blogspot)

Make Mindanao the country’s main agro-fishery export zone.

(Philippine Medium-Term Development Plan, 2000–2010)

It is in the troubled subregion of Mindanao, the largest Philippine island, that this fishery case study is situated. Even though the proportion of hungry Mindanao households more than quadrupled between 1998 and 2017, the government continues to target the island for agricultural crops (mostly nonfoods), capture fishing and aquaculture for export.1 To fuel its export growth agenda since 1980, the Philippines has exploited the rich ecological resources and farmlands of Mindanao. This island is pivotal to national economic growth goals because it generates 40 percent of agricultural crops, 42 percent of the country’s seafoods, and vast amounts of minerals and timber. In its Medium-Term Development Plan (Republic of Philippines 2000: 34), the government targeted Mindanao to be the country’s primary agro-fishery export zone. In 2007, northern Mindanao was the second fastest growing regional economy in the country (Philippine Sun Star, 26 July 2007). It is within the context of northern Mindanao’s past and contemporary high-pressure development agendas that we will examine the transformations that have occurred in the food extractive enclave we have chosen to examine. Located in northern Mindanao, (see Figure 3) Panguil Bay is surrounded by ten municipalities and two cities in three provinces (see Figure 12). The Bay and its fishery resources provide food and livelihoods to more than 11,000 registered full-time fishers, as well as thousands of undocumented part-time fishers, in 78 small coastal communities. These communities supply agricultural crops, industrial outputs, and vast amounts of fish and shellfish to the country’s GDP.2 Because it is one of Mindanao’s richest ecosystems, Panguil Bay was transformed into a food exporting enclave through nationally-set development goals. In the sections that follow, we will examine the restructuring of three major regional food production systems: agriculture, capture fishing, and aquaculture.

FIGURE 12
FIGURE 12

Municipalities in three provinces surrounding Panguil Bay in Northern Mindanao

1 Transformation of Panguil Bay Agriculture

Agricultural households are the poorest families in the Philippines, and agrarian reform has not succeeded at redistributing land to a majority of peasants (Ledesma 1982; Putzel 1992; Borras 2007; Borras et al. 2007). “The hacienda system still persists in the country, where large estates are farmed by sharecroppers. More than half the population are peasants, and 20 percent of the population own 60 percent of the land. Although the sharecropper is supposed to receive half the harvest, most of the peasant’s actual income goes toward paying off the debts incurred with the cacique, the landowner” (Third World Guide 2001: 438). According to the Asian Development Bank (2005: 60–61), “landless sharecroppers often depend on large landowners for credit to cover as much as 80 percent of the required farm inputs, such as seed and fertilizer.”

In its development plan for the 1990s, the government prioritized the conversion of more than 3 million rice and corn hectares to export crops, spurring land conversions in the Panguil Bay provinces (Republic of Philippines 1992). In its plan for the first decade of the 21st century (Republic of Philippines 2000), the government set new export targets for production of crops with “high-value” global demand and called for livestock output increases to spur growth in export food processing. To implement these goals, the government sought foreign agribusiness investments in northern Mindanao and Panguil Bay in (1) cattle, hog and chicken production (primarily through contract farming); (2) livestock feed milling; (3) meat processing; (4) cultivation and processing of fruits and vegetables with high global demand; (5) refurbishing of existing tree plantations (coconut, bananas, rubber) through introduction of new varieties; (6) expansion of ornamental horticulture and (7) biofuels production. Nationally between 1995 and 2008, the value of exported meats and meat preparations increased tenfold while the value of exported vegetables and fruits nearly doubled.3 Since 2006, the government has subsidized and sought foreign investments for new industrial tree plantations (especially oil palm) and has targeted some traditional food crops (e.g., cassava) for biofuels production (Republic of Philippines 2000: 29–36). In the 2010 national development plan, two million additional hectares were targeted for agribusiness production in biofuel crops and oil palm (Gironde et al. 2016: 117). Consequently, “a rural proletariat has emerged to work as contract labourers on plantations owned by large landowners or controlled by major multinational corporations” (Ness 2021: 33–34). Since 2010, domestically-cultivated sugar has been redirected into the production of bioethanol (Manila Times, 20 Jan. 2010).

1.1 Declining Cultivation of Cereals

The Philippines replicated patterns of export agriculture throughout the Global South. Historically,

trade in primary products entails extreme costs for the exporting country because it leads to the decline in the output and availability of basic food staples. … The inverse relation– between rising agricultural exports and falling domestic food grain availability– is repeatedly seen… in every case of the trade liberalisation of a developing country. (Patnaik 2011: 34)

Food crops for local consumption have been marginalized and devalued by Philippine development goals, and the export goals exceeded the available land along Panguil Bay. As a result, these national agendas spurred legal and illegal conversions of food crop lands. Nationally between 1995 and 2007, there was an 8.5 percent increase in croplands, but the Panguil Bay area lost more than 14 percent. The number of regional farms decreased by nearly 3 percent, and the average size of farms diminished to 2.7 hectares (NSO 2004). Most of those regional cropland losses occurred in cultivation of rice, causing higher rice shortfalls per capita than is true for the country as a whole. Nationally between 1995 and 2009, ricelands increased by nearly 21 percent, but Panguil Bay provinces were committing 9 percent fewer hectares to rice cultivation by 2009. Even though Misamis Occidental farmers cultivate vast highly-visible tracts of rice, this province commits only 12 percent of its cropland to grains. In the two municipalities of Aurora and Tambulig, there is only about 0.3 hectare of rice to every hectare of bananas and coconuts. Because of land conversions and ecological degradation since 1990, this region has been transformed from rice self-sufficiency to a zone that is dependent on rice imports.4

Panguil Bay provinces suffer more limited access to dietary grains than does the rest of the country. Since 1995, the Philippines has employed hybrid seed varieties on fewer hectares to generate a 21 percent increase in rice production. Over the same period, Panguil Bay rice production declined 2 percent. On the one hand, regional provinces have not benefitted equitably from the national irrigation program. Regional irrigated farm area declined 22.4 percent between 1990 and 2008, so only about 13 percent of regional farms were irrigated (NSO 2004).5 On the other hand, many rice farmers are too poor to afford the higher-yield hybrid rice seeds and chemical inputs that must be utilized if farmers are to be eligible for government subsidizes and credit (Interviews).

Similar declines have occurred in corn, the primary grain consumed by one-third of Bay households. Nationwide, corn lands declined very little between 1995 and 2009, but Panguil Bay corn hectares diminished by nearly 15 percent. While national corn production expanded 70 percent, regional output increased only 7.5 percent. Nationally, land use for grains increased more than 10 percent between 1995 and 2009, accompanied by a 62 percent rise in production. In contrast, Panguil Bay provinces lost nearly 11 percent of their grain lands, so the region exhibited less than a 3 percent increase in outputs. Local officials and NGO staff reported that some corn hectares were converted to fishponds in the 1990s. Moreover, the tradition of planting corn beneath coconut trees has been increasingly abandoned. Despite these trends, Panguil Bay provinces export grains through regional brokers. Nationally, the value of 2009 exported cereals and cereal preparations was five times greater than the 1995 level, driving the transfer of grains to Manila for processing and re-export. Throughout northern Mindanao, most of the rice is “sold through middlemen without a fixed price. A large quantity of rice production is transported outside the region through several middlemen who purchase the product at farmgate prices. Only a few farmers sell their produce to the National Food Authority (PDA 2009b: 2).”6

1.2 Prioritizing Commercial Export Crops

National policymakers prioritize an “agribusiness approach to countryside development” that values larger farms over small producers. Following the export principle that “high-value farm crops, vegetables and fruits have higher income potential than the traditional staple crops of rice and corn,” the Philippine plan (Republic of Philippines 2000: 29–34) sets goals that ignore peasants, including:

  1. “pursuit of a market-driven strategy that will link supply capacity closer to the high-impact markets,”

  2. promotion of national and foreign investments in agribusiness approaches and in infrastructure to support exporting,

  3. “a large-scale program of non-traditional high-value crops in farms and fisheries,”

  4. “increased production intensity” in existing crop, livestock and fishpond hectares,

  5. reconfiguration of “existing agricultural and fishery production systems to be able to tap emerging markets with vast potentials,”

  6. “value-adding through innovative packaging and agri-processing technologies” (e.g., freezing, cold storage, canning, drying), and

  7. cultivation of “idle and marginal lands” (i.e., mangroves) with export fruit trees.

The government makes its intentions clear: its goal is to “transform farmlands into agribusiness enterprises.” As for the people, “all these initiatives will result in the creation of a new class of farmers and fishers” who increase and diversify the marketable surpluses of their farms.7 In short, this is a plan to depeasantize the country’s agriculture, to concentrate most of the production into the hands of fewer larger holdings and to rationalize the labor process through greater reliance on modern technologies and imported artificial inputs. In this plan, the policymakers target “unsustainable practices” of impoverished peasant farmers, ignoring the massive levels of degradation that result from the country’s largest farms and tree plantations. Since Mindanao was targeted to be “an agribusiness hub,” Panguil Bay farmers have been harshly impacted.

Between 2008 and 2019, the country allocated more than one-third of croplands to rice. In the Panguil Bay region, however, rice is cultivated on less than 15 percent of all farm land. In sharp contrast to national trends, there is only one hectare of rice to every 5.6 hectares of crops that are not used for local consumption. Following development recommendations from the World Bank and IMF, the Philippines moved toward designating “high value export crops” and toward generating the resources needed to sustain that export-led agenda. Through subsidies, research and public advocacy, the government prioritizes commodities that it claims will generate the greatest foreign exchange or provision growth in other export sectors. In 2009, nearly half of all the country’s croplands were devoted to nonfood and export crops, but the impacts were worse in the Panguil Bay area. Nationally, more than 46 percent of agricultural land was being utilized for domestic crops, but only 24 percent of Panguil Bay agricultural land was growing domestic foods.8

In 2009, Mindanao was again targeted for an intense phase of agro-industrial development (Mindanao Magazine, 20 January 2009). A high proportion of the crops that the government targeted for expansion for export were produced in Mindanao (Menguita-Feranil 2007: 4). More than 43 percent of the country’s farms are situated in Mindanao, producing 87 percent of the country’s pineapples, 77 percent of bananas, 58 percent of coconuts, and 56 percent of corn. For that reason, the government earmarked $19.1 billion for agribusiness infrastructure and the expansion of “high-value” export cash crops in this region between 2007 and 2010 (Minda News, 17 June 2009). Regionally, 72 percent of farm hectares cultivated nonfood crops to generate exports and to provide feeds for the burgeoning meat, chicken and aquaculture industries.9

In Panguil Bay communities, coconuts are planted on nearly three times as many hectares as rice and on 1.7 times as many hectares as all crops for human consumption. Because coconut oil is one of the country’s most valuable industrial exports, nearly 86 percent of coconuts are utilized for nonfood purposes. Corn is also disappearing from the human diet due to the convergence of two trends: the decline in corn hectares since 1995 and increased nonfood usage. Several mills along Panguil Bay process corn into livestock and aquaculture feeds, leaving less than 18 percent for human consumption. Cassava is another traditional food that has been redirected outside the human diet. The vast majority of this crop is exported for industrial uses, but the government has also targeted this crop for future biofuel production. As a result, less than 10 percent of cassava was available for human consumption in 2010. In addition, the region cultivates abaca (hemp), rubber, and tobacco. Because it is indigenous, the Philippines produces 84 percent of the world’s abaca for industrial purposes.10 In 2001, the Philippine government set national biofuel goals for expansion of palm oil tree plantations.11 By 2006, the government was exploring the processing of corn, rice and sorghum hybrids into ethanol (Borras et. al. 2007: 1560). In 2019, one of every eighteen hectares, nearly 6 percent of the country’s agricultural land, was being used to grow oil palm and other biofuel crops.12 In addition, ornamental crops emerged in the region, as evidenced by a large flower farm we photographed near Tangub City.

By 2009, less than one-quarter of regional farmlands were being used to cultivate crops primarily for human consumption (see Table 13). Instead, Panguil Bay produced a disproportionate share of nonfood crops that fuel the country’s pursuit of exports. Between 1995 and 2009, regional production of coconuts and cassava doubled while increasing only about 15 percent nationally. In addition to nonfoods, Panguil Bay communities allocate four percent of hectares to the cultivation of the government’s targeted fruit and vegetable exports. In 2008, this region exported nearly 20 percent of fruits other than bananas, and almost 13 percent of vegetables, cashews and peanuts. Indeed, Panguil Bay provinces were more deeply embedded in this long-term export agenda than the country as a whole. Nationally between 1995 and 2009, fruits targeted for export increased less than seven percent while Panguil Bay fruit outputs nearly tripled. In 2009, fruits were being cultivated on more regional hectares than any other targeted food export, primarily reflecting the external marketing of nearly 60 percent of banana production. Similarly, Panguil Bay export vegetable production tripled over this period while national outputs climbed only half that much. Even though nuts targeted for export declined 24 percent nationally over this period, the output of cashews and peanuts doubled along Panguil Bay.

TABLE 13

Food insecurity in Panguil Bay communities, 2019

Part A. Rice insecurity
Production MT 143,430.2
(MT milling & storage losses in processing) (50,200.6)
(Production Reserved for Seed) (1965.2)
(Production diverted to animal/fish feed) (6,457.2)
MT domestic supply available for consumption 84,807.2
MT Consumption requirements to supply adequate food for local residents 108,763.9
MT Surplus or (Deficit) (23,956.7)
Part B. Fish insecurity
Production MT 149,815.8
(Production regionally diverted to animal/fish feed, plus wastage) (49,439.2)
(Production exported) (52,435.5)
MT Domestic supply available for consumption 47,948.4
MT Consumption requirements to supply adequate food for local residents 294,287.0
MT Surplus or (Deficit) (246,412.1)

SOURCES: ANALYSIS OF SUPPLY AND UTILIZATION ACCOUNTS, RSSIS. POPULATION BY AGE GROUPS FROM OPENSTAT. WE USED REPORTED ANNUAL PER CAPITA CONSUMPTION RATES OF 126.84 KG RICE AND 38 KG PER YEAR FISH FOR PERSONS OLDER THAN TEN, WITH 71.67 KG RICE AND 19 KG FISH FOR PERSONS YOUNGER THAN 10 (PHILIPPINE ANNUAL FISHERIES PROFILE 2018: 64)

Panguil Bay was also nationally targeted for increased beef, pork and chicken production (Republic of Philippines 2000), and it is in this sector that regional agriculture exhibited the greatest transformation. Because regional pork is primarily consumed locally, processed hogs declined 17 percent. In contrast, processed poultry rose more than 35 percent because the country exported nearly one-quarter of its dressed chickens. By 2010, poultry production accounted for 15 percent of the total value of the country’s agricultural exports, and quail raising for export increased four-fold. Between 1990 and 2009, Panguil Bay chicken processing increased nine fold, but this regional expansion was five times greater than the national level. Most of the expansion in this sector results from regional contract farming with two multinational corporations. There were 63 commercially processed chickens to every head of cattle, and 32 chickens to every hog being grown on Panguil Bay farms (NSO 2004). These trends reflect loss of available local food sources, as the traditional pattern has been for farms to grow small numbers of hogs and chickens for household consumption. Reflecting government export agendas, chicken processing increased four times more than fruits and vegetables that have been targeted for export.13

2 Transformation of Capture Fishing

Even though fish is the second most important food in the Philippine diet, government development goals since 1980 have emphasized the expansion of seafood exports. Capture fishing accounts for two-thirds of Panguil Bay fishery production. Peasant fishers target the coastal waters and rivers of their municipalities while large commercial vessels plunder both Bay and ocean waters. Even though Panguil Bay encompasses only 0.6 percent of the country’s coastal water and 1.2 percent of the country’s population, this region produces a disproportionate share of the country’s captured fish. In 2008, Panguil Bay area fishers produced 3.4 percent of all captured fish (NSO 2007; BFAR 2008). Like the rest of the country, this region has undergone major fishery transformations over the last three decades. In 1995, capture fishing accounted for nearly 97 percent of production. By 2009, declining biodiversity had caused capture fishing to decrease to about half that level.14

Most Philippine and Asian scholars and policymakers use the term artisanal fishers to refer to small producers who engage in capture fishing in near coastal and inland waterways. Throughout our subsequent analysis, we break with that tradition to use the term peasant fishers. The vague category “artisanal” has been used in ways that essentialize very large populations as traditional small operators, often merging more affluent fishers who employ modern technologies with poorer fishers who rely on a few cheaper gears. To avoid this clouding of the differences among fishers and to be able to situate our research against the backdrop of contemporary depeasantization debates, we have moved away from the artisanal categorization. Since so many public policies ideologically blame small fishers for more ecological degradation than their fishing technologies can possibly cause, it is important to distinguish the impacts that different groups of fishers have on their ecosystems.

2.1 Traditional Peasant Capture Fishing

Capture fishing is undertaken by three categories of independent operators. About 29 percent are middle class peasants who rely on traders and wholesalers to finance more exploitative gears that generate daily fishing incomes of $3 to $5. Another 1.5 percent of the region’s fishers use large commercial vessels and ply both municipal and ocean waters. However, 69.5 percent of capture fishers are poor peasants who generate daily per capita incomes of less than $1.00 (see Figure 13). At this point, it is important to emphasize that Philippine peasant fishers mirror global trends. Worldwide, 5.8 million fishers earn less than $1.00 daily, but the vast majority of these households are concentrated in Asia (World Bank 2012). Historically, Panguil Bay has been home to peasant fishers who rely on small non-motorized boats and simple net technologies that can be cast by a small group or attached to the cross bars on their canoes. Traditionally, capture fishing in the coastal waters and crustacean gathering in the mangroves have been the major sources of livelihood for peasant fisher households (interviews). Until 1980, peasant fishers produced a majority of the fish, shellfish and crustaceans consumed locally. As late as 1988, they captured more than 70 percent of the region’s seafoods. By 2000, commercial fishers in large vessels were dominating production by capturing 45 percent of fish. By 2007, the share of regional fish production caught by peasant fishers had shrunk to about one-fifth. Over this period, the government prioritized the exploitation of Panguil Bay by commercial fishers. Development philosophy has advocated restriction of peasant access to Bay resources in order to make way for strategies that effect higher mass productivity and increased export value.15 However, this public agenda does not reflect the realities of the lives of a majority of the peasant population who have few assets and even fewer few livelihood options.

FIGURE 13
FIGURE 13

Panguil Bay fishers and fishing, 2019

SOURCE: PHILIPPINE ANNUAL FISHERIES PROFILES (AVERAGES FOR 2010 TO 2019)

In 1969, small capture fishers averaged twelve kilograms daily using traditional technologies. During the 1970s and early 1980s, a peasant fisher could make a good catch of finfish in less than two hours and net a few crabs. In 1992, peasant fishers captured 1.3 tons to every ton extracted by commercial vessels. By 2000, the marketable species in Panguil Bay had declined nearly 30 percent, but most peasant fishers could not compete with the larger commercial vessels that needed to go deeper into the ocean to catch them. At that time, more than half the fish captured from Panguil Bay had lower market value, and the average daily peasant catch dwindled to less than a kilogram by 2008. Fishers complain that fishing and crab gathering are almost dead because of the decline in marine species. Since 2000, a fisher feels lucky to catch a kilogram of finfish per day and only rarely catches one or two crab that are much smaller than those caught two decades ago.16 On average, peasant fishers market daily only 36 to 91 US cents worth of fish, so most of them fall below the World Bank demarcation for absolute poverty. The species that is most significant among captured seafood exports is tuna which is predominantly harvested by commercial operators. Between 1992 and 2008, the Philippines tripled its tuna production, and Panguil Bay area commercial fishers generated one-third of that output. In 2007, tuna accounted for nearly 11 percent of total municipal fish production and more than 34 percent of commercial production in Bay communities. The Panguil Bay area accounted for 17 percent of national production, and tuna accounted for 20 percent of the value of all regional fishery exports.17

2.2 Depeasantization of Capture Fishing

By 1995, national fishery goals had changed dramatically, spurring the use of larger exploitative technologies by the small number of commercial fishers. In 2007 along Panguil Bay, 136 commercial operators harvested two-thirds of the captured fish while more than 15,000 peasant fishers generated the rest. Small and mid-size boats in municipal waters averaged about four kilograms daily while commercial vessels averaged 333 kilograms (BFAR 2007). While peasant fishers average daily catches of about three-quarters kilogram, more affluent fishers employ exploitative technologies to acquire commercial-level catches. Financed by regional wholesalers or absentee investors, these fishers install large stationary nets in Panguil Bay or operate small commercial boats on shares (Interviews). By 2008, peasant fishing was marginalized from natural resources by capital-intensive commercial capture fishing and aquaculture. Since a majority of Panguil Bay fishers do not own much equipment, the largest catches are controlled by the minority who utilize exploitative equipment. Even simple technologies are not very widespread among fishers. The bamboo crab pot outnumbers any other mechanism, but only about one-third of fishers own them. Motorized boats can double the fisher’s daily capture through the use of more complex gears, but only about one-fifth can afford them (or the diesel fuel). The crab lift net, the bottom set long line and the bottom set gill net are owned by 11 to 29 percent of fishers. Large stationary high-catch nets (i.e., bungsod, fish tower, and sangaab) are operated only by 1 to 4 percent of fishers who are financed by traders. The scoop net captures the largest daily catch, but it is owned by only 0.2 percent of fishers.18 Such mass production strategies generate three-quarters of the regional production, and a high proportion of those seafoods is being exported. Higher-value species comprise 80 percent of the fish captured by commercial fishers while three-fifths of the catch of peasant fishers consists of lower-value smaller species that will be consumed locally (BFAR 2008).

Because they are permanently installed over larger areas of the Bay, trader-financed stationary nets average daily catches that are two to eight times greater than those attained by peasant fishers with simpler equipment. Annually, a bungsod can capture twice as much as the typical production of one peasant who uses simpler technologies. Between 2005 and 2015, there were at least 648 bungsods permanently stationed in Panguil Bay, each averaging annual catches of 1.5 metric tons. Combined these nets hauled out nearly 1,400 metric tons, an amount of fish that would have required nearly 1,300 peasant fishers to capture (see Figure 14). Each year, a fish tower ensnares three times more seafood than a productive peasant boat owner. There were 141 giant fish towers permanently installed in Panguil Bay, each averaging an annual catch of more than 2.6 metric tons. There were also 543 massive sangaabs, each averaging an annual catch of nearly 2.7 metric tons. Nearly 2,000 peasants struggled to catch as much as these two types of technology withdrew from the Bay’s resources.19

FIGURE 14
FIGURE 14

Average annual metric tons captured by peasants and illegal stationary gears along Panguil Bay, 2005–2015

SOURCE: PHILIPPINE ANNUAL FISHERIES PROFILE (AVERAGES OF 2005 TO 2015)

Local and national attempts to ban these stationary nets from Panguil Bay have been unsuccessful. For a five year period in the 1980s, Panguil Bay was closed to several intensive gears, including sangaab, bungsod, crab lift net, gill net, cast net, and troll line (Dickinson 1987: 226–27). The ban proved ineffective, as it excluded any fisher who used a boat weighing less than three tons. An FAO report described the banning as an assault on “external intruders,” indicating that most exploitative gears were financed by external commercial operations (Baland and Platteau 1996: 14). In 1990, officials destroyed 1,600 net systems and uprooted several hundred net posts in the Bay. However, the gears appeared again almost immediately, and there has been no subsequent political will to eliminate them. As a result, there are nearly the same number of the most exploitative gears on Panguil Bay as there were in the 1980s. In 2005, there were nearly 1,400 stationary netting systems installed in Panguil Bay (MSU Naawan Foundation 2006). Combined, these exploitative gears withdrew 4,086 metric tons from the Bay, an amount that requires nearly 5,500 peasant fishers to capture with simpler technologies.

Illegal gears that were prohibited a decade ago are still operated all over Panguil Bay, both openly and covertly.20 In our interviews and those conducted by MSU Naawan Foundation (2006), peasant fishers indicated that exploitative gears were a primary cause of fishery depletion and, therefore, a threat to their livelihoods. Because these stationary gears require high capital investment, peasant fishers point out that they are not enterprises of the poor. Interviewed fishers reported that construction of illegal sangaabs and fish towers are “usually financed and their operations controlled by capitalists who are fish traders, fish processors and exporters. … The capitalists are considered so influential, financially and politically, that it would require a strong political will to dismantle the illegal structures that dominate Panguil Bay’s seascape” (MSU Naawan Foundation 2006: 185–86). National policy labels them “passive fishing gears” that are “viable alternatives to fish hunting in the wild,” ignoring that these technologies exploit far more resources than traditional methods. Couching these gears as “nondestructive,” BFAR officials conduct training sessions and distribute this equipment to Panguil Bay fishers who can finance them (Philippine Star, 13 June 2010).

3 Transformation and Expansion of Aquaculture

Capture fishing dominated the Panguil Bay Region until the 1990s, supplemented by traditional aquaculture. In the early 1950s, there were 2,022 hectares of regional fishponds that specialized in polycultural production of milkfish and shrimp that were fed with natural inputs through water exchanges. During the 1970s, major transformations occurred as a result of structural adjustment programs and new national development policies. Between 1951 and 1977, the total fishpond area along Panguil Bay expanded 437 percent. Since more than 6 percent of fishpond hectares were situated here, the national shift to export-oriented aquaculture fell disproportionately on this region. Because of its hydrological characteristics and confined waters, Panguil Bay was targeted by the government for further aquaculture expansion in the 1980s (Gauran 2003), and aquaculture hatcheries exhausted Bay resources by withdrawing high quantities of shrimp and fish broodstock (Tumanda 1982). As a result, 9.2 percent of the country’s fishpond area was operating here in the 1980s.21 Then fishpond hectares expanded another 50 percent after the 1988 Agrarian Reform Act permitted owners to shield their holdings from redistribution by converting them to aquaculture (Borras et. al 2005). Consequently, this region experienced one of the highest levels of land conversions in the country (Umehara and Bautista 2004).

3.1 National Trade Crisis and Regional Expansion of the 1990s

When the country caught “shrimp fever” in the 1980s, most Panguil Bay communities did not. A majority of regional fishponds continued to specialize in milkfish for local consumption until the early 1990s.22 After the national crisis of the late 1980s and early 1990s in shrimp exporting, the country began targeting virgin territories of northern Mindanao for expansion of this commodity (Republic of Philippines 1992: 34). By 1995, nearly 13 percent of the country’s fishponds were operating in this region. Despite its small coastal water area, Panguil Bay ranked 28th in the country in its aquaculture outputs during the 1990s.23 As regional outputs of export shrimp rose sharply, milkfish production for domestic consumption dropped. Between 1998 and 2003, Panguil Bay was nationally targeted for increased fish farming of tilapia and milkfish and for intensification of seaweed farming. Some abandoned shrimp ponds were converted to milkfish production, and export seaweed production was intensified (JEP-ATRE 2004). Until the late 1990s, aquaculture production rose slowly and gradually along Panguil Bay, but the so-called rehabilitation efforts of the late 1990s stimulated even greater exploitation of regional resources (Roxas et al. 2009). By 1995, fishpond development had expanded to 28,250 fishpond hectares that consumed 14 times more land area than 1951 aquaculture. Regional fish and shellfish production in ponds began to rise sharply in the late 1990s, and aquaculture production has continued unabated since then.24

FIGURE 15
FIGURE 15

Exploitative fish harvest technologies. The top diagram shows a sangaab, the net system that produces the most massive catches from incoming tide waters; there were 543 of these installed in Panguil Bay in 2014. The bottom photo shows one of the 648 bungsods, most of which are managed by middle-sector peasant fishers who are in debt bondage to traders or financiers. These expensive technologies average annual harvests that are four to eight times greater than those attained by the most productive peasant fishers using traditional gears

3.2 Aggressive Aquaculture Promotion Since 2000

In line with the development thinking of external funding agencies that vast areas of the Philippines “are still under-utilised with respect to aquaculture” (FAO 2004b: 3), the country’s early 21st century fishery policy advocates “aggressive promotion in all regions” of export-oriented aquaculture (Mulekom et al. 2006: 552), especially in Mindanao. Because 43 percent of the country’s aquaculture production occurs there (Menguita-Feranil 2007: 3), government funds were earmarked for “realizing Mindanao’s agribusiness and aquaculture and mariculture potentials” (Republic of Philippines 2000: 59). Mindanao was expected to triple exports of aquaculture products to China quickly.25 The Philippine Chamber of Commerce advocates that “aquaculture production in Mindanao offers opportunities for growth, with a variety of species available. Mindanao is an ideal location…due to its large production areas and year-round fish production” (PIA News, 17 September 2008). The President of Cruz Aquaculture repeated this position when he told the Sixth Mindanao Food Congress that “Mindanao can increase its aquaculture production and can compete with other Southeast Asian countries. … We can have better production because we have big territorial waters” (Manila Bulletin, 20 August 2007). When the Philippines opened its seafood industry to intensified foreign investment in 2002, policy changes hit Mindanao hard. More than 40 percent of Japanese and Chinese trade agreement goals target this island (Escobar 2004: 39). To cement the role of the Philippines in the ASEAN Free Trade Zone, the Asian Development Bank provided funds to improve the country’s export infrastructure, a sizeable segment aimed at Mindanao. Regional fishing ports were constructed to facilitate export, and six refrigeration facilities were developed (ADB 1999: 12).26 To maximize export durability, twenty processing plants were opened, including eight canneries that can process 300 metric tons daily (Mindanao Magazine, 20 April 2009). The government also promoted fishpond transitions to new species, most of them genetically-modified. For example, the government funded twelve tilapia hatcheries in which it cultivated 60 million fingerlings of genetically-modified tilapia for distribution to commercial fishponds (Asia Pulse, 8 December 2004). Tilapia production was targeted to expand after “conversion of large tracts of land in northern Mindanao into fishponds in line with the project to promote export of tilapia filets to the US” (Aguiba 2004). After Vietnam earned $1 billion from catfish fillet exports to Europe and the US, Vitarich Corporation introduced this species to Mindanao by marketing fingerlings and specialized feeds (Mindanao Magazine, 26 May 2008).

Since 2000, the government has targeted new production strategies in the ocean that it claims will overcome ecological problems of fishponds. The Philippines recruited foreign investments to establish most of its forty mariculture parks in Mindanao (Philippine Star, 23 July 2006). A typical park is 500 hectares or more, with farm plots for fish cages and seaweed farming. Adjacent to these parks are ancillary facilities, such as ice plants, cold storage, canneries, feed mills, and sea cage fabrication (Agribusiness Week, 29 April 2009). Much like a publicly-subsidized industrial park in the US, the mariculture park represents an attempt to rationalize aquaculture production into a vertically-integrated commodity chain. The stated goal is “to develop an area with appropriate equipment and infrastructure that will allow fishermen, fish farmers, and investors to operate cost effectively and securely” (Rosario 2006: 9). The government also “promoted partnerships with foreign investors to intensify commercial fish cage farming,” like the Zamboanga City Mariculture Park (Manila Bulletin, 23 February 2008). To move fish to market as quickly as possible, the government developed a “mariculture highway” system that connects Mindanao parks to ports, in order to “enable the country to be an important player in the live food-fish export market.”27 Though government subsidized, these mariculture parks offer few opportunities for small-scale fishers because they encompass large-scale fishponds established by traders, urban financiers, foreign investors and powerful local officials (Palanca-Tan 2018: 309–310).

In addition to continuing pressures from international development agencies, the United States broadened its funding of “high-value aquaculture” in Mindanao, around three agro-industrial goals: (1) “significant expansion of production and marketing of several lucrative, non-traditional commodities;” (2) establishment of “cold and cool chains” to allow substantial expansion of fresh fish exporting; and (3) stimulation of “a major expansion of exports to the large and growing China market.”28 To “accelerate economic growth in Mindanao,” USAID funded several infrastructure projects that process and store aquaculture and mariculture outputs, including boat landings, port upgrades, road construction, a multi-species hatchery, a mariculture park, a seaweed warehouse and seaweed solar dryers. A new grouper and abalone hatchery in southern Mindanao is operated by Mega Fishing Corporation, a deep sea purse seine operator that ships canned fish to 22 countries. The US Department of Agriculture “Buy USA” website makes clear why the US is funding aquaculture projects in Mindanao: the potential import of American technology, building materials and hardware. The US Embassy Mindanao Initiative and the US Commercial Service stimulated joint ventures between US and Philippine companies, and many of these partnerships offered American investors a four to six year tax holiday, a low income tax rate, and guaranteed 50 to 75-year leases. Buy USA declared that “Mindanao is the Philippines gateway to opportunity,” and it recommended that American businesses export to Mindanao agribusiness and food processing machinery, solar power systems, refrigeration and cold storage equipment, plastic aquaculture building materials, chemical test kits, and flat-rolled iron. Buy USA claimed that “Mindanao has a strong affinity for US brands,” so it recommended that US farmers export wheat, milk and soy products to the region. In fact, the Bureau of Fisheries and Aquatic Resources cooperated with USAID to try to expand the use of soy-based feeds in aquaculture. In short, the US presence in Mindanao was intended to develop new markets for US agricultural and industrial products.29

For the Panguil Bay area, the primary export goal is to “supply upscale foreign markets” with “high-value, high-demand aquaculture products, such as humpback grouper, tiger prawns, blue crab, sea cucumber, abalone” (Philippine Daily Inquirer, 1 January 2009). To accomplish that, two national goals were set for the Panguil Bay region. First, aquaculture was expanded through the introduction of new genetically-modified species (e.g., tilapia) that were in global demand and through construction and operation of hatcheries and input facilities. Second, the country recruited partnerships with foreign investors to intensify commercial fish cage farming.30 Since 2000, the government has funded several support services to move the region toward a broader aquaculture agenda. Two mariculture parks of 695 hectares were constructed in Lanao del Norte and Misamis Occidental. A fish health lab has opened in Ozamiz City (Media Monitoring Report, November 2004), as well as a marine finfish hatchery in Misamis Occidental. Grow-out cages were established in Panguil Bay to produce fry for cultivation of grouper, milkfish, red snapper, crablets, and seabass (Philippine Daily Inquirer, 1 January 2009). To facilitate long distance shipments of seafoods, ice and cold storage facilities were constructed in the region. A processing plant at Ozamiz City prepared regional fish and shellfish for export to Manila and the world (BFAR 2008b).

These aggressive aquaculture development strategies have stimulated deeper exploitation of regional resources. By 2008, regional aquaculture production was 29 times greater than the 1984 level, but aquaculture outputs grew at less than half that level nationally. By 2005, there were 68 percent more Panguil Bay fishpond hectares than there were in 1988 when the bust stage of shrimp farming hit the country so hard. Between 1995 and 2007, regional aquaculture production more than doubled, and this sector grew more than any commodity except processed chickens. While encompassing less than one percent of the country’s coastal waters, this region generates a disproportionate share of the country’s aquaculture production. In 2008, this small region produced nearly 17 percent of national shrimp output, more than one-third of the country’s mudcrab, but less than 2 percent of national finfish production. While most areas of the country expanded freshwater facilities, nearly 8 percent of the country’s highly-polluting brackish water fishponds were located along Panguil Bay. By 2019, more than 90 percent of the output of national fishponds was milkfish and tilapia (part of which is consumed domestically) while shrimp for export accounted for more than half the output of Panguil Bay fishponds.31

FIGURE 16
FIGURE 16

This fishpond specializes in shrimp, and the Panguil Bay region generates nearly 17 percent of the country’s production of this export commodity. However, fishponds like this one do not generate local employment. One laborer handles daily feedings and repairs, and he earns such a low wage that he must engage in part-time capture fishing while his wife must secure additional income from the informal sector

4 Integrating the Panguil Bay Fishery into National and Global Commodity Chains

The battle over ecological resources that has played out in Panguil Bay communities is not unique to this small area of the Philippines. Indeed, the transformations are a result of the integration of this area into the capitalist world-economy and its global food system. Multinational corporations integrate resource-rich zones, like Panguil Bay, in order to locate new supplies of raw materials, cheap labor and new markets for the commodities they move among the vast network of trading countries (Hopkins and Wallerstein 1987). In order to restructure an untapped region into a food extractive enclave, key capitalist actors take political and economic control over targeted ecosystems and their populations in order to reorganize them for export production. Public commons are eliminated through various forms of private enclosure that limit access rights of the peasants who predominate in this space. To cement this process, public policies are modified to encourage the agglomeration of large holdings of land and waterways. Essentially, access to ecological resources is redefined to transfer surpluses from local peasant producers into the hands of export-oriented capitalists. Once land tenure and access to ecological resources have been restructured, the regional environment can be articulated with the world-economy (Dunaway 1996: 276–85). In order for communities and their ecosystems to be transformed into extractive enclaves that export foods, existing domestic production sectors must be minimized or displaced to make way for the creation of new economic activities.

4.1 Export Functions of the Panguil Bay Region

Since the 1970s, the Panguil Bay region has undergone massive transformation of its relations of food production to become restructured around export activity. Panguil Bay’s resources and fishers have been integrated at three levels. First, Panguil Bay is a production regime in which fishery production has been restructured in response to the country’s international market agendas. Moreover, it is an extractive food enclave that transfers commodities to Manila to be processed for re-export to foreign markets. Second, this region is an ecological extractive enclave that provisions the rest of the country through exports of raw materials to support productive systems in other regions of the country (e.g., fish baits, livestock and aquaculture feeds, hatchery inputs). Third, Mindanao rural areas feed the rest of the country. Panguil Bay communities have been fundamentally changed as the island of Mindanao has been embedded into export chains that move food commodities to the National Capital Region. Consequently, the external trade linkages of Panguil Bay communities have been restructured to move a majority of fishery commodities to Manila where the country’s largest agribusinesses, food processors, and exporters are concentrated.32 Manila acts as an entrepot to process raw materials into value-added commodities for re-export to foreign markets and for re-distribution inside the country. Because Mindanao produces more of the country’s food supply than any other region (Republic of Philippines 1992), the government developed a logistics system to deliver the island’s outputs more rapidly to Manila (Minda News, 17 June 2009). “We have a food security problem,” the Secretary of Agriculture told the Third Aquaculture Congress in Mindanao. “So we need Mindanao to ship more of its products, and we need its food to help feed the 15 million people of Metro Manila” (Minda News, 30 November 2004).

4.2 The Spatial Articulation of the Region’s External Trade

Like the rest of the country, Panguil Bay communities have been articulated with global markets through a multi-level distribution structure in which absentee foreign and national investors and a regional comprador bourgeoisie (Amin 1976) monopolize natural resources and control the flow of food commodities. Networks of regional petty capitalists, brokers, commission merchants and wholesalers are integrated into the commodity chains that transfer regional exports to national wholesalers and processors. Spatially, the villages, towns and cities of the Philippines are hierarchically structured into interlocking zones of production, distribution and consumption. To effect external trade nationally, layers of markets are connected between small villages, regional trading hubs and city bulking centers, commodity importing cities, and trade entrepots. In the Panguil Bay region, the largest cities (e.g., Ozamiz City, Tangub City) are hubs of commercial interaction with other regional communities and with distant territories. Consequently, the region’s larger cities gradually became “foreign bodies” in their local economies, “looking beyond [their] narrow surroundings and out towards the greater movement of the outside world” (Braudel 1981, 2: 117). Export commodities are centralized in these towns where wholesalers, larger traders, merchants and manufacturers are located. Capitalist trading triggers a network of commodity chains in which larger trading hubs subsume nearby smaller communities. In this way, the fragile local economies of the region’s small fishing villages are integrated into the spatial organization of the global food system and into world industrial markets for several nonfoods. Small villages move commodities to towns that have better access to transportation or are more commercialized. From these regional cities, trade goods move to Manila and a few other national trading hubs that provide export linkages for the distant transport of bulky or perishable produce and import linkages for the wholesale distribution of foreign commodities. Local officials and NGO staff estimate that there is a 100 percent profit markup by the time commodities reach Manila. Government policymakers have observed that “raising agricultural and fishery production and competitiveness have not automatically and consistently led to increased farm income” because “an inordinate share of the benefits from higher production goes to middlemen” (Republic of Philippines 2000: 20). In the sections that follow, we will explore the actors and mechanisms through which fishery commodity chains have been constructed to integrate Panguil Bay communities more tightly into national and global markets.

Regional aquaculture production was transformed in the 1990s to move toward specialization in shrimp production for export. Indeed, when compared with production of all finfish through both capture and aquaculture, shrimp exports have been central to Panguil Bay fishery goals since 1993 (BFAR 1993). Between 1988 and 2007, the proportion of regional fishery production represented by shrimp rose steadily. On average since 2000, shrimp accounted for 40 percent of annual seafood output. By 2019, Panguil Bay communities were generating nearly 18 percent of the country’s shrimp and more than one-third of its mudcrabs. Very little of these commodities is marketed locally, except for that small proportion that will not meet export standards. The national goal is to ship abroad as much as possible of these commodities in the fresh/near-fresh state in order to capture the highest prices from countries like Japan (BFAR 2007).33

4.3 The Crustacean Commodity Chain

Smaller producers of shrimp and crab enter these commodity chains through their ties to local consignment traders who sell on commission to small-scale wholesalers who buy in bulk (see Figure 17). In the Panguil Bay region, shrimp and crab are usually taken to buying stations in Taguitic, Tangub and Ozamiz Cities, and these wholesalers rely on local agents who maintain direct contact with fishers and fishpond operators. Four Kapatagan wholesalers buy and transport about a ton of shrimp and crabs to Manila every day, as do wholesalers at Bonifacio. Eleven wholesalers situated in Aurora and Tambulig also export about a ton every day. Wholesalers finance shrimp farms, botilleros who specialize in crab capturing or middle-class peasant fishers who employ large stationary nets. In these contexts, the producers either are paid a share of their output (a sharecropping arrangement), or they repay indebtedness by marketing their produce to the wholesalers who finance them. These wholesalers pay in advance for stock to be harvested, typically specifying to the fisher or fishpond operator the quantity and quality of the commodity. These centralized marketing stations maintain ice facilities and processing plants where the commodities are sorted and prepared for export to Manila. If a regional wholesaler is financed by a national broker, the commodities will be shipped directly to this agent in or near Manila. Some producers sell directly to itinerant agents (viajeros) of Manila agribusinesses who travel around the Bay communities to make purchases.34

FIGURE 17
FIGURE 17

Commodity chain for Panguil Bay shrimp, prawns, and crabs

SOURCES AND NOTES: INTERVIEWS, PHILIPPINE ANNUAL FISHERIES PROFILE (2000–2019), BFAR WEBSITE. FINANCE AND CREDIT LINKAGES ARE INDICATED BY TWO-DIRECTIONAL ARROWS

While large fishponds market directly to national wholesalers or processors with whom they have financial or corporate ties, shrimp marketing is more tedious and precarious for smaller producers. The small pond operator must book the sale of a harvest with a buyer who sets the delivery price based on an average body weight that will meet export standards. If the shrimp output does not meet those standards, the buyer will either reject the crop or lower the sale price. In this way, the lowest quality shrimp output may be marketed locally through small vendors in wet markets. In some instances, the small pond operator sells lower quality outputs to a commission trader who disposes of it at low prices to a processor of sauces or mixes. From Panguil Bay communities, the consignment trader transports the commodities to a regional auction, usually at Taguitic or Migpange, where large loads are purchased by agents for national broker or corporations. At Manila, four types of national agents come into play: brokers, corporate representatives, wholesalers or processors. At this level, all the crabs and the highest quality shrimp are sorted and reserved for foreign export. That part of the fresh/frozen shrimp output that is headed abroad will leave the country within a day’s time, but crabs may be air lifted within hours of the catch. Also in Manila, processors prepare shrimp for re-export and for redistribution within the country.

4.4 The Finfish Commodity Chain

As Figure 18 shows, regional marketing of finfish is far less vertically integrated because it involves more transaction points than is the case with shrimp and crabs. In contrast to the shrimp commodity chain, the finfish chain has greater numbers of small traders and larger mid-sector traders, and the path to Manila can be so circuitous that fish can be traded four or more times before reaching a national wholesaler, processor or exporter. Independent peasant fishers enter the commodity chain through small fish traders or cooperatives that market their catches in local public markets, to local retailers or to wholesalers that buy in bulk. However, a majority of peasants either fish on shares or market their catches to a small fish trader or a regional wholesaler who finances their operations.35 Small fishers are trapped in an untenable position. “If they sell their produce, increasingly they lose part of the value by repaying debts to the commercial operators or town dealers who finance their trips and buy part of the catch. Some brokers finance hundreds of canoe fishermen at a time” (Krinks 2002: 134–135).

FIGURE 18
FIGURE 18

Commodity chain for finfish produced in Panguil Bay communities

SOURCES AND NOTES: INTERVIEWS, PHILIPPINE ANNUAL FISHERIES PROFILE (2000–2019), BFAR WEBSITE. POTENTIAL FINANCE AND CREDIT LINKAGES ARE INDICATED BY TWO-DIRECTIONAL ARROWS

For instance, tuna exporters have thousands of fishers under contract. Typically, small tuna boat operators produce on shares with the wholesalers or processors who finance them. A wholesaler/broker extends credit advances or equipment financing to a boat owner against future catches. “By financing the cost of the fishing operations, the trader is assured of a steady supply of tuna. … Traders generally dictate the going prices of tuna to the disadvantage of the producers, who feel the pricing scheme is cartelized since traders often [set] the same pricing cap” (Vera and Hipolito 2006: 44, 56). Wholesalers do not always accept the highest bid for traded tuna, as they prefer to market to a “preferred client” who can pay cash. Consequently, the producer may not be paid the most competitive price. Some boat-based wholesalers buy directly from small or mid-size boat crews, paying lower prices than the fishers could receive if they directly marketed their catches to land-based wholesalers. In sharp contrast, the 43 commercial tuna boats market directly to a wholesaler.

Wholesalers employ contract farming to control more production of tilapia and milkfish. In these cases, the wholesaler advances capital, equipment and aquaculture feeds, so the producer can generate fish at standards and prices set before production. Construction of capital intensive stationary fishing nets (e.g., sangaab, bungsod) are “usually financed, and their operations controlled, by…fish traders, fish processors, and exporters. This arrangement ensures a ready market for the harvested fish; the buying price, however, is dictated by the capitalists, to the disadvantage of the fishermen” (MSU Naawan Foundation 2006: 185). Large corporate fishponds often finance smaller fishponds and market their outputs. Regionally, six exporters operate trading stations, and their local agents operate on commission for distant exporters who advance funds to be used to finance local fishers. Because a majority of small fishponds have been financed by traders, two-thirds of milkfish is marketed through wholesalers who buy in bulk. Payment is delayed to producers, as the fish is sold through silent auctions. Wholesalers load (or require producers to do so) finfish into 33 kilogram containers for auction. However, the trader (and the subsequent buyer) pays for 30 kilograms, externalizing to each producer an arbitrary charge for spoilage or product damage during transport to a distant market. In this way, risk from the trader’s handling is shifted to the producers.

In addition to their structured linkages to Manila, these regional commodity chains exhibit four striking features. First, these are noncompetitive trading chains in which a few wholesalers/brokers dictate terms and conditions to many producers and to lower level traders. A majority of fishers and small fishpond operators are financed by, and must market their outputs through, wholesalers who have the capacity to manage long-distance transport, the technology to prevent spoilage, and the linkages required to market the commodities at the national and/or international levels. Indeed, there are numerous points in the commodity chains at which the lower level producer or trader is financed by the next higher level. Second, the commodity chains are polarized between those agents who market the most profitable seafoods that will leave the country in fresh/frozen form and those that handle finfish.36 Because shrimp and crabs have the highest market values nationally and globally, the trade chains for these commodities are much more vertically integrated than the trade in finfish. The handling of the most expensive commodities is more rationalized among fewer layers of agents to insure expeditious transport to Manila or foreign markets. Third, the largest producers hold a market competitive position while small producers face three disadvantages. Financed fishers and fishpond operators must market their outputs noncompetitively to the investors to whom they are indebted, so they cannot competitively seek out higher prices. Thus peasant fishers or small fishpond operators are not able to reject or to bargain up the prices at which their commodities are sold. Since smaller operators are already controlled through credit terms, wholesalers do not view them as “preferred clients” to whom they need to extend special favors to sustain supply flow. Moreover, there are several points at which producers can be cheated or have their output quantities diminished in favor of the trader or wholesaler. For instance, producers are never paid for the full quantity of their outputs because wholesalers shift to producers the risk of spoilage losses by discounting the weight 9 percent or more (Interviews). Finally, only lower quality seafoods are targeted for local markets. Small fish vendors sell locally those fish catches that have such low commercial value that wholesalers will not purchase them. Smaller regional wholesalers and consignment traders sell to local retailers bulk supplies that have little commercial value, including substandard tilapia and milkfish. Purcell (2017) estimates that Asian small-scale fishers average 50 percent of the retail value for the lowest-value species (most finfish) and 10 percent for the highest-value species (shrimp, lobsters, crab, live reef fish).

4.5 The Live Reef Fish Commodity Chain

Live reef fish and exotic species are the most valued commodities in the Asian fishery trade (SEAFEDC 2017: 142). Throughout the Coral Triangle of the Philippines, Indonesia and Malaysia, more than 35,000 small-scale fishers exploit coral reefs, 27,000 of them situated in the Philippines. In 2009, the Philippines provided more than half the exports for the live reef fish trade which is valued at $2 billion annually. Since the 1990s, the primary driver for this trade has been the demand from Hong Kong and mainland China restaurants for exotic live finfish (especially grouper), mollusks (e.g., oysters, clams), shellfish (e.g., lobster, crabs) and cepahlopods (e.g., squid, octopi, sea cucumber). Even though product scarcity triggers higher prices, demand continues to rise because consumers prefer live species over pond and cage-produced commodities. A majority of the reef species are exported by air to Hong Kong, then re-exported to Shenzhen where the largest Chinese wholesalers are located. From there, the live reef commodities are distributed throughout mainland China by specialized trucks. Fewer than twenty major traders, middlemen and exporters collectively handle the reef fish trade in Hong Kong and China. Secondarily, fishers capture species for the ornamental species trade that is valued at nearly $1 billion yearly; these live species are marketed for American and European aquariums. Since 2010, a tertiary market has developed to sell juvenile fish and “trash fish” to operators who hold and grow smaller species in marine cages until they reach a larger, more profitable size (Elliott and Jang 2011; Maclean and Sadovy 2003; Padilla et al. 2003).

Most of the reef fishers are small-scale independent operators who have few viable livelihood options. Reef species often provide four to six times the average price for non-reef species (Burke et al 2002: 30), so fishers are willing to take on debt for the $700 initial investment in boats and gear (Maclean and Sadovy 2003: 36). As a result, at least one of every 51 Philippine peasant fishers is enmeshed in the trade through a system of debt bondage that embeds them in a oligopolistic commodity chain that consists of a handful of regional middleman traders that operate collection stations for Manila-based exporters (Padilla et al. 2003). In this regard, Panguil Bay fishers have much in common with other rural Asians, for such arrangements are common throughout the Asian fisheries (see Table 14). Middlemen provide boats, gear and loans to fishers who repay the debt in installments by marketing their catches exclusively to these oligopolistic traders (Elliott and Jang 2011).37 “The fishermen take their catch to the middleman and sell it at the prevailing price. When catch is low, or during lean periods, the middlemen provide for [fishing gear repairs and household necessities]. … Payments are made in the subsequent fishing expeditions until the debt [including interest] is fully paid. As conditions become dire, the more indebted the fishermen become. The situation often leaves them in debt all year round and subsequently fully dependent on income from the live reef fishing trade to pay off debts” (Padilla et al. 2003: 6). The catch fisher receives about 30 percent of the price received by the middleman for the exported commodity (Maclean and Sadovy 2003: 34). Even though wholesale prices at Hong Kong range from $11 to $63 per kilogram, the typical Philippine reef fisher averages less than $50 monthly, before debt payments (Burke at al. 2002).

With 25,060 square kilometers of coral reefs, the Philippines is ranked among the world’s coastal areas that have the highest levels of marine biodiversity (Spalding et al. 2001). The overfishing and destructive fishing methods associated with the live reef trade have seriously degraded Philippine coral reefs. By 2017, 90 percent of Philippine coral reefs were in fair to poor condition, compared to 93 percent of reefs around the coasts and bays of Mindanao (Licuanan 2017). In addition to severe overfishing of reef species, two illegal destructive fishing methods are utilized to maximize production quickly. Poisons are the predominant method used to capture high-value reef fish. Divers apply sodium cyanide to reefs to stun fish. The process destroys many fish and can leave residues that are harmful to humans. The initial poisoning bleaches part or all of the coral, and repeated incidents can kill vast areas of coral. Some fishers employ dynamite or cheap handmade grenades. A typical beer-bottle bomb can leave a crater of rubble one to two meters in diameter, and regularly bombed reefs frequently exhibit 50 to 80 percent coral mortality (Burke et al. 2002: 28).

5 Is Philippine Fish Marketing Culturally Unique?

Panguil Bay residents apply colloquial terms to differentiate the economic power of the traders and marketing agents in the commodity chains that control the conditions under which they will be paid for their outputs.38 However, these kinds of commodity chains and the agents who manipulate them are not culturally unique to the Philippines. Regional seafood marketing reflects what Joan Robinson (1993) terms imperfect competition because of its monopsonistic features. Ten companies export three-quarters of all Panguil Bay shrimp, crab and finfish.39 With little competition, the monopsonist is able to dictate terms to suppliers, including prices, types of commodities and production standards. Because of control over limited services, such as transport of a perishable commodity to distant markets, these traders and brokers frequently pay different prices to producers who supply large volumes and those who are smaller producers. Consequently, the rate of exploitation of suppliers is high, for the value of the producer’s contribution to output is far greater than the price received. In monopsonistic contexts, the price of the good is pushed down as near as possible to the actual cost of production (or below). The middle-sector traders who are able to lower production costs the most have the greatest degree of monopoly in the commodity chain and will be able to collect a higher proportion of its assets and wealth. Clelland (2013: 73–74) explains that degree of monopoly is

the control of any mechanism that reduces the costs of production or increases sales prices in variance from a fully competitive market. … As a commodity moves up the chain, each capitalist usually has a greater “degree of monopoly” than those below. And that degree of monopoly is reflected in the capitalist’s ability to constrain the transmission of costs of production from below. Degree of monopoly is the ability to lower costs or raise prices beyond what would be possible in a purely competitive economy. Technically, this is a “degree of oligopsony” in which a few buyers control prices. The large wholesaler or retailer at the end of the chain may hold a true “degree of monopoly” through control of sales markets.

Once tied to a broker, a producer will receive lower prices than the value of the commodity in a marketing circuit that is competitive (Boal and Ransom 1997: 86).

For more than two decades, western scholars have observed that the power and profit in food commodity chains worldwide, “is to a significant degree a function of the most unique or least substitutable resources. In essence, the owner of the least substitutable resource has the most power to capture rents, transfer risks to others and have significant impact on what the chain does or does not do” (Boehlje et al. 1998: 400). In Philippine fish marketing, those agents are in the best position to dictate terms to producers who (a) have the resources to extend financing and/or (b) possess time and logistical advantages to move perishable commodities to distant markets. In the Panguil Bay region, those actors in the trading chain are at a significant advantage who can advance credit, who have the means to transport fresh seafoods, and who have access to ice, freezing or sanitary packaging mechanisms. Thus the weaker the financial and technological capabilities of the trader, the lower the profit that is extracted. Since they control “the least substitutable resources,” the commodity chain favors national wholesalers, processors and exporters. Furthermore, the greatest degree of monopoly in the chain lies with those capitalists who have established network ties to foreign markets. Consequently, these Manila-based agribusinesses and exporters expropriate the largest share of the profit that accrues from the commodity chain inside the country.

5.1 The Philippine Suki Tradition

Scholars who studied the country’s fishing communities in the 1970s and 1980s call attention to the suki linkages between fishers and fish traders, and a majority of Philippine analyses emphasize the exploitative aspects of this trade relationship. In the suki relationship, the fisher markets catches to the same buyer, who extends “favors,” such as credit. In the past, scholars have reported that Philippine fishers are “tied to particular buyers, known locally as suki, from whom they obtain credit and sometimes inputs, such as fuel, and to whom they must sell their catch, often at a 10% discount on price received” (Smith and Mines 1982: 22–23). According to Jocano and Veloro (1976: 110–27), the indebtedness of the peasant fisher is advantageous to the suki because it helps to insure a steady supply of fish. However, the suki acts in a noncompetitive fashion to set the price of the commodity below its market value and demands immediate repayment of loans if the fisher takes a catch to another trader. Many suki charge outrageous interest rates over time, but the system persists because peasants have no better means to obtain credit. While low-level suki relationships may have characterized local fish trading through the early 1990s, these small operators play a less crucial role in contemporary marketing. While small fish traders and municipal market-based suki still exist in great numbers, a majority of the Panguil Bay producers acquire financing for their fishing equipment from agents who operate at higher levels in the marketing system.40

There are several points in the commodity chains at which producers can become financially-bound to the buyers of their seafoods. Since 1995, credit and marketing have been interlocked at three levels. First, most poor peasants acquire credit from small fish traders who advance small amounts for household needs against future production. Second, at least 60 percent of the peasants fish on shares for traders or wholesalers who advance capital for boats, equipment, stationary net systems and household survival needs. Third, middle class producers acquire credit or financing from large exporters who are seeking to control fishery outputs into the future (Interviews). What has changed in the modern context is that small fish dealers and suki in municipal markets cannot finance the kinds of costly technologies that the most productive fishers and fishpond operators utilize. Being able to advance credit allows regional level wholesalers to capture a higher segment of the total production, and this is the degree of market monopoly that all traders seek to gain. On the one hand, national firms decentralize agents into regions like Panguil Bay, and these agents are able to extend higher credit levels than local suki. On the other hand, regional wholesalers often secure capital from national-level wholesalers or agribusinesses that advance funds to be used to insure monopsonistic advantages with producers.

5.2 Parallels in Other Countries

In sharp contrast to previous scholars who have analyzed Philippine fish trading as culturally distinct or “economically backward” (Szanton 1972), we would like to emphasize that this country’s marketing strategies and mechanisms are quite similar to food and fish marketing worldwide. The monopsony, small producer exploitation and debt bondage that characterize Philippine fishery commodity chains have been observed in fishing communities all over the Global South and several richer countries. These types of exploitative trading linkages continue to exist in the global food system because they are so profitable for the largest traders in the commodity chain. Rather than being “economically backward” structures that modern capitalists seek to obliterate, seafood marketing systems like those in the Philippines institutionalize mechanisms through which most of the risks are externalized to producers while minimizing their proportion of the total value of the chain. This country is not unique in its lack of competitive finance mechanisms for fishers, for credit has been employed in fisheries worldwide as a key method to control laborers and to acquire their outputs at below-market prices. “Smaller firms and individual producers are integrated into the operations of the big corporations as suppliers of raw materials and primary products. … Only those firms with high investment exposure and easy access to unlimited credit through close connection with the centers of political power manage to appropriate the greater bulk of the economic benefits” (Tadem et al. 1984: 6).

As in other countries, the greatest power and profit in Philippine fishery commodity chains accrue to those marketing agents who have inequitable control over or access to limited services that are crucial to the production and distribution processes, particularly (1) political or economic assets that favor some actors in the chain over others; (2) credit and finance; (3) transport mechanisms in areas where there are limited options for producers: (4) food preservation mechanisms and capacity to process foods to meet distant standards; (5) the most timely knowledge about changes in demand or prices in distant markets: and (6) ties to distant wholesalers and retailers. These features are not peculiar to the Philippines, as there are parallel rural fish marketing strategies in many countries.41 Indeed, this type of exploitative profit-taking by non-producers is “normal capitalism” at its best in the global food system. In addition to ecological surplus drains, transnational corporations transfer wealth to foreign countries through imported technology, technical and advising fees, interest on financing, and foreign manager salaries (Pelupessy and Vankempen 2005).

6 Ecological Impacts of Global Integration

Neither market prices nor production budgets take into account the value of natural resources nor the expense of repairing the degradation of the ecosystem that is caused by regional export activities. The entire island of Mindanao has paid high ecological costs for intense export-oriented development. The island has lost three-quarters of its mangroves, primarily to aquaculture growth, and it has been deforested at a rate that far exceeded the rest of the country (Philippines Daily News, 22 April 2003). In Mindanao, more than half the rivers are polluted, and only about 5 percent of the coral reefs are in good condition (Minda News, 17 June 2003). Mindanao waterways have been more ecologically damaged by mining and timbering than any other region of the Philippines (World Bank Philippines 2003). Similarly, the communities of Panguil Bay have paid high ecological costs for their integration into global markets. This region is one of the most damaged Mindanao fisheries, and it is in severe crisis due to nearly four decades of extreme exploitation. In recognition of the degraded state of fishing resources in the 1990s, the national government implemented a local recovery program (JEP-ATRE 2004). However, these conservation efforts failed miserably (MSU Naawan Foundation 2006). After a decade of so-called rehabilitation, the Philippines Environmental Monitor (World Bank Philippines 2003) declared Panguil Bay one of the most contaminated waterways in the country. Of the country’s seventeen most critical ecological hotspots, the Department of Environment and Natural Resources identified three that are situated along Panguil Bay.42 Despite the red flags raised by NGO s, fisherfolk associations, local government officials and external development agencies, the national government targeted Panguil Bay for more resource exploitation after 2000 (MSU Naawan Foundation 2006).

Panguil Bay is home to several diverse economic activities that are hazardous to the ecosystem. The water is polluted by chemical and organic residues from fishponds, industries, farms and beach resorts (World Bank Philippines 2003). As early as 1990, Philippine scholars were warning that chemical and industrial effluents were “capable of wiping out the fishing population” and of transforming Panguil Bay into “biologically dead waters” (Loquias 1991: 48–49). Alarmingly high levels of oil and greasy sludge kill turtles and fish, erode coral reefs, and choke mangrove trees. Massive fish kills have occurred after processing plants discharged chemicals, grease and oil into the Bay. Because the government does not provide public waste disposal systems, businesses and households dump into the Bay vast amounts of garbage, domestic wastes, and sewage (JEP-ATRE 2004). More than half of the farmlands surrounding Panguil Bay are suffering from moderate to severe erosion (Domingo 2001). Seasonal floods carry pesticides, lime, wastes (especially rice hulls), and soils from farms. Thus siltation has diminished the depth of the Bay and clogged its 32 connecting rivers (Gauran 2003). The quantity and quality of harvestable resources from the Bay’s coastal waters have declined due to capture fishing, pollution and waste. Commercial operators throw away one-third of their catches that they consider to be “trash fish.” This destroyed macroplankton contains “larvae of fish, crustaceans and cephalopods of commercial importance when allowed to grow to adult sizes. … When the number of macroplankton organisms hauled daily will be extrapolated from the number of gears operating in the Bay, the result can be quite staggering” (Naawan School of Fisheries 1996: 12).

Peasants emphasized three sources of the worst damage caused by capture fishing to Panguil Bay: (1) government failure to eliminate illegal fishing by commercial trawlers; (2) government unwillingness to remove the most exploitative stationary fishing gears from the Bay; and (3) government policies that stimulate illegal fishing by foreign vessels.43 In the words of one outraged fisher, sanggab (a stationary gill net) “devours the seas.” In 2015, the Panguil Bay Development Council announced a project to remove sangaabs (Enerio 2015). However, later published scholarship reported that the Bay is overexploited due to the continued use of stationary fish corrals and sangaab gilllnets (Jumawan et al. 2021). In 2008, local fisher organizations requested national intervention to stop large Japanese, Korean and Taiwanese vessels from capturing tuna, marlin and other high-value fish in Bay waters. Rather than addressing such peasant complaints, the national government ratified an Economic Partnership Agreement in October 2008 to permit Japanese canning vessels to exploit the seas adjacent to Panguil Bay. Fishers contend that this new agreement will result in a growing number of foreign commercial boats in Bay waters (Lazaro 2008).

Even though the government fishery program (BFAR 2006) points to small fisher strategies as major sources of marine depletion, peasant fishing tactics generate only a fraction of the shortages and degradation that have been caused by commercial capture fishing and aquaculture. Between 1982 and 2021, twelve studies examined the increasing ecological degradation of Panguil Bay, pointing to the impacts of fishponds and the multiplicity of nonfishing activities along the Bay.44 In its government-funded report on Panguil Bay rehabilitation, MSU Naawan Foundation (2006: 234) reported that “the depletion of resources is attributed to the continuing conversion of mangrove areas into fishponds, the toxic effluents of fishpond operations, and over-exploitation of resources by commercial fishers.” Despite earlier interventions to protect Bay habitats, mangroves declined 20 percent, seagrass cover shrank 20 percent, and hard coral cover dropped to 25 percent of their 1991levels (Roxas et al. 2009). Between 2015 and 2021, studies pointed to the continued decline of fish and crustacean species (Enerio 2015; Wilson et al. 2019; Jumawan et al. 2021). In recognition of the ecological problems associated with brackish water production, more than half of Philippine aquaculture outputs had been shifted to fresh water facilities by 2007. However, brackish water ponds still predominated along Panguil Bay after 2010 (Philippine Annual Fisheries Profile (2011–2019), and those fishpond effluents continued to cause decline of fish and crustacean species (Enerio 2015; Wilson et al. 2019; Jumawan et al. 2021).

Vandana Shiva (2000: 15) estimates that every acre of an industrial shrimp farm destroys or degrades 200 acres of productive ecosystem. Such damage is evident in this region. Due primarily to expansion of fishponds, Panguil Bay is surrounded by only 4.4 percent of the mangrove density that was present in 1950 (Roxas et al. 2009). Philippine fisherfolk associations point to the role of the World Bank and the Asian Development Bank in stimulating mangrove destruction. According to the fisher coalition Kilusang Mangingisda, “ADB and World Bank funds fueled the expansion of intensive aquaculture in Southeast Asia, which converted most mangrove areas for the large-scale production of shrimp and other species for export” (Philippine Daily Inquirer, 18 April 2008). The seemingly lush mangroves that border the Bay conceal the extent of the damage. “The area is actually hollow like a donut. The line of trees that one sees from the outside simply serves as a curtain to cover the continuing illegal and destructive exploitation” (MSU Naawan Foundation 2006: 216).

Despite negative fishpond impacts on the Bay, national and local government agencies have continued to promote fish farming. By 2005, the 18,000 hectares of Panguil Bay were dwarfed by 28,250 hectares of fishponds. Even though fishponds encompass an area that is 1.6 times the size of the Bay, these fish farms repeatedly dump their polluted waters into the Bay or its estuaries. As a result, fishpond sedimentation has shallowed the Bay, and pond chemicals threaten species survival. The diversity of seaweed and seagrass species has declined to fewer than one-fifth of 1991 varieties, coral reefs are endangered, and the diversity and numbers of fish stocks are “relatively poor” (MSU Naawan Foundation 2006: XXVXVII). At the turn of the 21st century MSU Naawan Foundation (2006: 178) reported that the only species still in abundance in Panguil Bay were “those that do not fetch high prices.” Indigenous crab had been so overfished that they were present in the Bay at only about 10 percent of their level in the late 1990s. Two decades later, mud crab production by peasant fishers had declined sharply, and this species had been severely overexploited by 2020 (Jumawan et al. 2021). Post-2015 ecological research indicates that government efforts to rehabilitate area mangroves failed, leaving this important ecological resource in an alarming state as a result of cumulative conversions to fishponds, tourist beaches and agriculture (Wilson et al. 2019).

7 Food Insecurity in Panguil Bay Communities

When a region is integrated into the world economy as a food extractive enclave, production activities that support local consumption are marginalized to diminish competition for limited ecological resources. At the same time, some foods that are central to the traditional diet are commodified. With the entry of the first wholesaler into a Philippine fishing village in the 1980s, “fish became not just of value as food but was instantly convertible to money or even other goods (like rice) that could be taken from the comprador’s store. … In effect, fish became money; both the value of delivered fish and a fisher’s debts would be recorded in the comprador’s notebooks” (Hagan et al. 2003: 342). What follows is a process in which locally consumed foods are “fetishized” in public policy formation as commodities that have “high value” in distant parts of the globe. Government policies privilege these new export sectors over domestic food security, shifting public funds for research, credit, and production subsidies to foods that have “market value” and away from foods for domestic consumption. Panguil Bay fishers who were youngsters in the 1970s point to their loss of many of the seafoods that their families traditionally consumed.

Less than thirty years ago, community residents met returning fishers on the beaches at break of day. Before fish was sold to brokers or traders, priority was given to distributing daily food requirements to households. Since 1995, fishers are primarily met by commercial agents who export fish. Residents point to the disappearance from local fresh markets of top quality shrimp, crabs, squid, octopus, seaweed, sea cucumbers, fresh tuna, and numerous other seafoods that have been targeted for increased export. They also explained that they can no longer afford these foods, even if they were available. Many women report that they can only buy the shrimp heads that have no commercial value (Interviews). To complicate matters, fishing households cannot afford nutritious fruits and vegetables that have been targeted for export (Ness 2021: 110). In the wake of this global process, Panguil Bay’s peasant fishers have lost economic and political autonomy in their traditional food spaces, and their livelihoods have been displaced and marginalized by export-oriented capture fishing and aquaculture. Within three decades, the Panguil Bay region has been transformed into a food extractive enclave that sends away vast amounts of the survival needs that once were allocated to local populations.

7.1 Declining Local Consumption

The regional re-orientation of productive assets to prioritize exports has led to serious shortfalls in rice and seafoods, the traditional pillars of the Philippine diet. In 2007, local consumption needs exceeded the available rice supply by nearly 24,000 metric tons, representing a shortfall to nearly one-quarter of the population (see Table 13) Threats to local consumption of seafoods are even worse. Once we take into account exports and conversions to feeds, less than one-third of 2007 fishery and aquaculture production was left for local human consumption. In 2007, there was a deficit of 246,412 metric tons. Indeed, local consumption requirements were six times greater than the available supply of fish, shellfish and crustaceans. In this context, fishery commodities are too scarce and too expensive for a majority of Panguil Bay households, especially those that are highest in iron. “Only fish traders can afford to buy pansat [shrimp], alimango [crab] and pugapo [grouper]. Once very abundant in the wild and consumable items on the fishers’ tables, these seafoods are collected, cultured or fattened and exported to outside markets (MSU Naawan Foundation 2006: 234, 265).

Why has local consumption declined? First, fewer of the available ecological resources are utilized to generate foods for local consumption, and three-quarters of farm hectares are growing nonfood or export crops (see Table 13). Thus there is only one hectare of rice to every 5.6 hectares of crops that are not eaten locally.45 Prioritization of export aquaculture has further exacerbated the situation. While other Asian countries were less likely to convert croplands to fishponds between 1975 and 2000 (FAO 2004b), that threat to food security was quite obvious along Panguil Bay. By 2005, more than 82 percent of fishponds were situated on private lands that had once grown crops.46 What is even more alarming is the ratio of fishponds to croplands. In 2010, the region had one fishpond hectare to every 4.6 hectares of croplands for domestic consumption.47 Moreover, there was one fishpond hectare to every 2.8 hectares of rice. In aquaculture, export-oriented production of shrimp and a few species of finfish have been prioritized over seafoods for local consumption, so regional production of milkfish declined steadily between 1984 and 2000. Production of milkfish began to rise again after 2002 when the national government began to target this variety for export.48 Fetishized as a “high value” seafood that will attract future foreign exchange, traditionally consumed milkfish has risen in value so much that local prices were 1.5 times higher in 2009 than they were in 2000 (BFAR 2000–2009).49

7.2 Conversion of Nutrients to Nonfoods

Many seafoods that were once consumed as part of the human diet have been redirected into nonfood uses. According to the fisher coalition Kilusang Mangingisda, export-oriented aquaculture has led to massive loss of wild foods in mangrove areas and to dwindling fishery stocks (Philippine Daily Inquirer, 18 April 2008). Because aquaculture facilities require three kilograms of fish protein to every kilogram produced (BFAR 2006), Panguil Bay mollusks and shellfish have been depleted to a crisis point. Fishpond operators gradually worked their way downward through four increasingly smaller shellfish species, competing with the human food chain to redirect natural resources to feed shrimp. Amahong and burnay, two species of mussels that have been a traditional part of local diets, are nearly extinct due to uncontrolled, unregulated and continuous harvesting to collect feeds for shrimp production.50 Once these two species were in limited supply, punaw was the next marine resource depleted to feed the shrimp farms. Punaw are so limited that this traditional food shellfish is expensive in local markets. After punaw were diminished, fishpond farmers substituted agihis which are also threatened. Once plentiful in the shallow coastal waters, these small fish are now concentrated in deeper waters and are difficult to harvest. In addition, nearly 13 percent of the local seafood supply is processed into fishmeal and fish oil to be used as additives in aquaculture and livestock feeds. Nationally, 55 feed mills integrate fish and shellfish into feeds (Bestari and Morales 2005: 15–16), so there is increasing demand for smaller, cheaper fishes from Panguil Bay for this purpose. Poor peasant fishers are alarmed about what next will disappear from their ecosystem, as they have observed declines in crabs, shrimp, larger fish species, clams, and small food fish and shellfish over the last three decades (Interviews). According to Primavera (2000: 102), “Philippine fisheries are so degraded, fish supplies are so inadequate, and people are so poor that they need fish of all sizes and prices.” In 2008, however, exports and nonfoods accounted for nearly 88 percent of Panguil Bay aquaculture production. Milkfish, the species most consumed by Filipinos, is increasingly targeted for nonfood use. While there is an inadequate supply of milkfish to meet local needs, the national government is encouraging use of milkfish as bait to catch tuna.51

The transformation of seaweed from part of the traditional Filipino diet to a “high-value” export commodity is instructive. In 1998, the Philippines ranked third among seaweed producing nations, rising to second in 1999. By 2001, seaweed cultivation accounted for two-thirds of the country’s total aquaculture output in tons (Albor 2002). The Philippines specializes in three types of seaweed exporting. The country is the largest carrageenan chips manufacturer globally and the world’s third largest producer of refined carrageenan, annually shipping to Spain, Denmark, France, India, and the United States 115,000 metric tons of semiprocessed seaweed worth $69 million, most of those exports deriving from Mindanao. In addition, 22,500 metric tons are exported annually as seaweed extracts valued at $105 million (BFAR 2009). Peasants indicate that several varieties of seaweed were gathered from the wild for the local diet in the 1970s and 1980s when there was no commercial production along Panguil Bay. Between 1988 and 2000, the region averaged less than 60 metric tons annually, and most of this was consumed locally. Due to national demand for more seaweed output to support national manufacturing of carrageenan for export, Panguil Bay production rose sharply after 2000.52 By 2008, regional seaweed farms were producing nearly 36,000 metric tons, an output level that was 968 times greater than the 2000 production. In 1988, tuna and shrimp accounted for 80 percent of the market value of regional seafood exports while the market value of seaweed was minuscule. By 2005, the value of regional seaweed exports exceeded tuna, shrimp and crabs– even though this nonfood sells at a far lower prices than the seafoods. Less than one-third of Philippine seaweed output is used as food, but most of that is exported in dried form to Japanese and Chinese markets.53 Moreover, gathering from the wild has been rendered dangerous by the periodic upsurges of “red tide” toxins that have been stimulated by aquaculture expansion all over Asia.54

8 Looking to the Future

Just over a decade ago, peasant fishers in the other Asian fisheries altered their dependence on local traders. By 2010, most Asian peasant fishers sold two-thirds of their output directly to large wholesalers in towns and cities, often as a direct reflection of their debt bondage to those agribusinesses (Siar and Kusakabe 2020: 23). In the Philippines, small scale fishers continue to market their catches locally to traders to whom they are indebted, a monopsonistic process that involves several layers of middlemen who collect more of the profits than the fishers. Middleman profiteering, debt bondage, and illegal labor trafficking are central economic elements of the 21st century Asian fisheries (see Chapter 8 for more detail).

A brief assessment of government market philosophy regarding shrimp and seaweed provides insight into the outdated economic notions of “high-value commodities” that still dominate national and international thinking. While shrimp and seaweed are fetishized by Philippine government agencies as the most profitable export crops, there is much market mythology and misjudgment represented in this rhetoric. The interests of a few exporters may be reflected in these agendas, but the realities of the world market are not. First, the Philippines prioritizes seaweed export, even though it is one of the lowest-priced fishery commodities in world markets. Once globally dominant in export of seaweed, the Philippines is now dwarfed by China. Still the country has increased its imports of this commodity since 2000 in order to be able to manufacture more carrageenan for export.55 Second, the market position of shrimp has been volatile throughout the decades that the national government has advocated and subsidized its production. The number of producers of shrimp worldwide has multiplied tremendously since 1980, primarily because international development agencies encouraged so many poor countries to enter this export arena. Since the 1980s when China became the world’s largest shrimp producer, the Philippine position in world markets has declined sharply, and it is doubtful that the country will ever regain a competitive position in the global food system. When market prices are standardized for comparability over time, we see that the country is losing economic ground. In 2006, the country received only one-third as much for a ton of this commodity as it did in 1988 (see Figure 19). One Philippine economist recommended in 2009 that the country import foods in order to prioritize the production of “high value exports,” like shrimp, that offer a “comparative advantage” in world trade (Philippine Business Mirror, 8 June 2009). Even in 2009 when this position was taken, Philippine shrimp were no longer competitive globally. By 2019, a metric ton of Philippine shrimp was worth only 37 percent of its 1988 international value. While the country risks food insecurity and ecological degradation to produce shrimp, this export commodity no longer holds either the “high value” or the global “comparative advantage” that this economist touted a decade ago. In its emphasis on “large-scale production and commercialization,” the country’s five-year fishery plan for 2022 to 2027 calls for a continuation of this failing “development framework.”56

FIGURE 19
FIGURE 19

Price paid per metric ton of shrimp/prawns exported from the Philippines, 1988–2019

SOURCE AND NOTES: PHILIPPINE ANNUAL FISHERIES PROFILE (1988–2019). VALUES WERE CONVERTED INTO 2010 $US FOR STANDARDIZED COMPARABILITY OVER TIME

1

Analysis of Philippine nutritional surveys (PNFRI 1994, 1999, 2017). Throughout this chapter, all monetary values are $US.

2

Analysis of crops, OpenSTAT; Philippine Annual Fisheries Profile (1978–2015); MSU Naawan Foundation (2006).

3

Aggregation and analysis of exports, UN COMTRADE.

4

Analysis of land utilization and food balance sheets, FAOSTAT. Analysis of provincial and municipality websites (accessed March 2017). Aurora and Tambulig are situated in Zamboanga del Sur province.

5

Analysis of land utilization, FAOSTAT.

6

Analysis of exports, UN COMTRADE. Aurora municipal website (accessed March 2017). The term “middlemen” accurately reflects the gender of this sector of traders.

7

In its policy formulations about peasants, Republic of Philippines (2000, 2010) reflect World Bank influence. See Chapter 8 for a discussion of “the new agriculture” that was proposed by the World Bank (2007).

8

Analysis of land utilization, food balance accounts, OpenSTAT and FAOSTAT.

9

Analysis of land utilization, food supply and utilization and exports, OpenSTAT and UN COMTRADE.

10

Analysis of supply and utilization accounts, FAOSTAT. In addition to biofuels, coconut oil is used as an additive to soap, cosmetics, automotive and industrial lubricants, and margarine. Coconut water is used in intravenous medical solutions (Shetty and James 1994). Cassava has only limited food use. A majority of the world’s cassava is used in adhesives, corrugated boards, wallpaper, paper, clothing, plastics, stain removers, concrete, detergents and dusting powders (Pattron 2008). Abaca is used in manufacture of rope, stiff clothing and footwear, tea bags, meat and sausage casings, cigarette papers, and currency notes (Agribusiness Week, 28 April 2009).

11

USFAS news, 6 Jan. 2001.

12

Analysis of country data, FAOSTAT.

13

Analysis of crop production data, FAOSTAT.

14

Philippine Annual Fisheries Profile (1995–2009).

15

Analysis of Philippine Annual Fisheries Profile (1988–2019).

16

Elder fishers claim they once captured crabs as large as unhusked coconuts.

17

Analysis of Philippine Annual Fisheries Profile (1992–2010) and BFAR (2008). Scad (12 percent), sardines (10.7 percent), mackerel (4.6 percent), and anchovies (4.4 percent) were among the marketable fish, but these are not the most valuable seafoods for export.

18

Analysis of Philippine Annual Fisheries Profile (2006–2019) and MSU Naawan Foundation (2006: 90–93).

19

For descriptions of these gears, see SEAFDEC (2005). Stationary gears function year-round, so a 365 day fishing season is assumed for them. A 260 day fishing season is assumed for non-stationary gears.

20

Sangaab, fish tower, dredge (motorized sudsud), and fine meshed gill nets are illegal (MSU Naawan Foundation 2006: 195). We saw and photographed many of these nets.

21

Analysis of Philippine Annual Fisheries Profile (1977–1990).

22

Analysis of Philippine Annual Fisheries Profile (1980–2000).

24

Analysis of Philippine Annual Fisheries Profile (1977–2012).

25

USAID-Philippines website (accessed 15 April 2019).

26

Many of these public facilities are leased to private enterprises.

28

USAID-PH website (accessed 15 April 2019).

29

“Buy USA” website (accessed March and April, 2019).

30

BFAR Region 10 website, BFAR website (accessed 14 Sep. 2019).

31

Analysis of Philippine Annual Fisheries Profile (1984–2019).

32

Analysis of national directory of agribusinesses and exporters, DA website (accessed 10 May 2019).

33

Analysis of Philippine Annual Fisheries Profile (1988–2019).

34

Interviews with local officials and NGO staff.

35

With respect to fish trading, we employ the non-sexist phrase “middle-sector traders” to reflect that there are a few women in this group. Some small fish traders join together to purchase and market fish, or smaller traders will market the fish of a larger trader. The colloquial term amot-amot is applied to specify such arrangements.

36

There are four other fishery commodity chains that we do not describe. Dried fish is marketed through a commodity chain that is separate from fresh seafoods. Two registered exporters/processors (A.C. Field Trading, E.R. Pon Trading) specialize in dried sea cucumbers. In peasant households, women dry, salt and/or smoke oysters and fish of lower commercial value. Sea cucumbers are re-exported as a delicacy to Japan while dried fish and smoked oysters are primarily distributed to local agents of distant city retailers. Seaweed is marketed through its own commodity chain of traders, wholesalers and agribusinesses.

37

For more live reef fish commodity chain details, see Padilla (2003: 6–7).

38

These terms include consignacion (consignment trader who sells on commission), rigaton (large wholesaler who buys in bulk for re-export), comprador (large wholesaler who buys fish).

39

BFAR Region 10 website (accessed 12 July 2019).

40

Several Philippine scholars (e.g., Jocano 1983) have reported that the traditional suki relationship had nearly disappeared from many of the country’s fishing villages by the early 1980s. For scholars who point out the exploitative aspects of suki in fish marketing, see Abad et al. (1986), Davis (1973), Hopkins and McCoy (1976), Jocano and Veloro (1976), Sevilleja and McCoy (1979), Smith and Mines (1982), Spoehr (1984), Panayotou (1985), Torikari (1990), Yotopoulos and Floro (1991).

41

For studies of Asian countries, see Mai (1984), Klein et al. (2003), and Ferdoushi (2010). For studies of non-Asian countries, see Brown (1976) about Argentina, see Larson (1985) about Egypt. For analyses of credit and finance mechanisms in fisheries of other countries, see Bailey (1988a), Barrett and Apostle (1989), Jomo (1991), Ibarra et al. (2000), Nadel-Klein (2000), Hagan et al. (2003), Neiland and Bene (2004), D. Gordon (2005) and Salmi (2005).

42

These are Aurora area damage caused by illegal logging, degradation of Olanguin River in Lanao del Norte, and threats to survival of Lake Duningagat in Misamis Occidental (DENR website accessed 11 Feb 2019).

43

We aggregated our household interview data with accounts of local officials and MSU Naawan Foundation (2006).

45

Analysis of land utilization, OpenSTAT.

48

Analysis of food balance sheets, FAOSTAT.

49

A majority of Muslim Filipinos live in Mindanao, and these communities exhibit the highest poverty and malnutrition rates of the country. Despite the food insecurity of their communities, the Medium-Term Development Plan (Republic of Philippines 2000: 34–36) authorizes government funding for the development of a special economic zone that will target traditional Muslim foods for export.

50

Interviews with a public technician at one of the BFAR Stations along Panguil Bay and with local fishers who harvest wild small fish to sell to local fishponds.

51

“Milkfish Commodity Roadmap,” BFAR website (accessed 8 January 2019).

52

“Seaweed Commodity Roadmap,” BFAR website. BFAR Region 10 website (accessed 8 January 2019).

53

Analysis of Philippine Annual Fisheries Profile (1988–2009).

54

BFAR website (accessed 7 Aug 2019).

55

“Seaweed Commodity Roadmap,” BFAR website (accessed 8 January 2019).

56

BFAR News, 22 Feb. 2022, https://www.bfar.da.gov.ph/BFARnews?id=457 (accessed 28 Feb. 2022).

  • Collapse
  • Expand