Introduction

Postimperial Synchrony: Industrialisation and Nation-Building as Entwined Processes

In: In the Shadow of War and Empire
Author:
Görkem Akgöz
Search for other papers by Görkem Akgöz in
Current site
Google Scholar
PubMed
Close
Open Access
Shortly before the First World War would cast a further shadow over the “sick man of Europe,” Rosa Luxemburg was working on the publication of a series of lectures she had delivered at the central school of the German Social Democratic Party. The then crumbling Ottoman Empire was one of the examples Luxemburg cited in what would become a popular work of economic history and theory on the complexity and unevenness of capitalist development:

A country like Turkey [has] a large surplus of imports, amounting in many years to almost double the quantity of exports. How can Turkey … afford the luxury of such a copious filling of the “gaps” in [her] “national economy”? … Do the Western powers offer the crescent … each year a present of several hundred million marks, in the form of all kinds of useful goods, out of Christian charity? Every child [knows] that … Turkey [is] actually up to [her neck] in the jaws of European usurers, and [has] to pay the British, German and French banks an enormous tribute in interest. … Turkey has virtually no industry of its own, and cannot conjure this out of the ground of its medieval peasant subsistence agriculture with its primitive cultivation and tithes. … And so not only the whole of the population’s needs for industrial goods, but also everything necessary for transport construction and the equipment of army and navy, has to be imported ready-made from Western Europe and constructed on site by European entrepreneurs, technicians and engineers.1

Two decades later, the leadership of the Republic of Turkey, the last nation-state to emerge from the ashes of the Ottoman Empire, decided it was time to break free from the shackles of underdevelopment so masterfully described here by Luxemburg. This gave rise to the first attempt outside the Soviet Union to set out an industrial plan. The preface to the first five-year plan of 1934 echoed Luxemburg’s analysis in an equally powerful tone, suggesting that the German-speaking Turkish bureaucrats may even have read her work, which had been published posthumously in 1925. The text referred to Western Europe and the eastern shore of North America as “the workbench of the world” that had destroyed the productive means of non-industrialised societies by selling them their manufactured products. The rationale for the plan, again similar to Luxemburg’s analysis, foreshadowed the basic premises of the Latin American dependencia school by more than three decades.2 For countries such as Turkey, this unequal exchange between industrial and agricultural nations, the authors of the plan argued, resulted in de jure independence but de facto dependence.

The industrialised powers, for their part, were able to set aside their existing conflicts to join forces in an effort to retain the agricultural countries as raw material producers, which they saw as a way of controlling their national markets. The onset of the Great Depression affected the latter more adversely than the former, but the crisis of the entire liberal world of the nineteenth century, as Eric Hobsbawm put it, also had a silver lining: the core countries temporarily lost their grip on the periphery, presenting a small window of opportunity for the underdeveloped nations to turn the tide.3 The crisis of world capitalism, the planners asserted, was a chance for the Turkish state to reverse the peripheralisation of the country by quickly building national industry.4

And so, postimperial Turkey emerged from long years of war and economic destruction with a new developmentalist plan to embark on an ambitious import substitution model of national industry-building. This was before state-led import substitution industrialisation would spread throughout the developing world in the years after 1945.5 The new economic policy was baptised “etatism,” a term used by French protectionists and socialists in the 1890s, which, in the economic life of the 1920s, came to mean direct state intervention. In 1935, the Republican People’s Party (Cumhuriyet Halk Partisi, hereafter the chp) adopted etatism as a party principle. Two years later, etatism made it into the constitution as one of the six principles of the republic, together with republicanism, populism, secularism, reformism, and nationalism. By the mid-1930s, Kemalism, the official ideology of the republic named after its founding leader, Mustafa Kemal, had a strong industrial component. As industry and technology were celebrated as the centrepieces of state-building, a factory system took shape in the 1930s consisting of old Ottoman factories and newly built ones. State factories emerged as key sites of entanglement, where questions of nation-building, class formation, and modernisation were intimately tied together. They were expected not only to buttress Turkey’s hard-won political independence with economic independence from the advanced industrialised countries, but also to set the standard for relations between capital and labour throughout the country.

The republic was barely ten years old when it embarked on state-led industrialisation. The first decade was characterised by turmoil, politically as well as economically. The Kemalist leadership engaged in a radical and wide-ranging programme of superstructural reforms to address the institutional and legal framework and cultural issues of the 1920s. After violently suppressing the first armed Kurdish rebellion under the republican regime in 1925, the government enacted the Law for the Maintenance of Order (Takrir-i Sükûn Kanunu), endowing itself with virtually absolute powers. It was at this point that authoritarian state-building began to gather momentum. By the time state-led industrialisation had begun, that momentum was in full swing.

The simultaneity of the two processes of postimperial nation-building and state-led industrialisation lies at the heart of this book. In the Shadow of War and Empire is a tale of these two distinct yet connected histories and the ways in which the interactions between them shaped and were shaped by working-class politics. The industrialisation efforts of the 1930s and 1940s and their consequences have their origins in the underdevelopment of the Ottoman Empire, an examination of which is essential for understanding the key characteristics and global connections of Turkey’s interwar economic policy. I therefore swerve the chronological marker that severed Turkey’s national present from her imperial past and reject the received wisdom that compares the Turkish republic to an “immaculate conception.”6 My first contention is that Turkey’s interwar state-led industrialisation can only be properly understood through a broader analysis of postimperial nation-building, one which neither reduces it to state actions nor ignores the relative autonomy of industrial relations.

If the aim is to trace the historical continuities in peripheral industrial development, there could hardly be a better starting point than a factory that was central to the two rounds of state-led industrialisation, separated by almost a century. And it is here that the story begins, at one of the old imperial factories that was taken over by the republican regime. In the Shadow of War and Empire explores the close relationship between nation-building and workplace relations under state-led industrialisation. The book offers a site-specific history of Ottoman and Turkish industrialisation through the lens of a mid-century cotton factory in the “Turkish Manchester,” the name chosen by the Ottomans for the industrial complex they had built on the northern shore of the Marmara Sea in the 1840s, which was taken over by the republican state in 1923. The building of this industrial complex marked a turning point in the prolonged process of the Ottoman state’s resistance and accommodation to capitalism in the mid-nineteenth century. During the interwar period, the factory was at the centre of another attempt by a new political regime to resist foreign control. In the contemporary words of one of the country’s most prominent Marxist theorists, the factory was “the secret to and the basis of Turkish state capitalism.”7 Both the imperial and the republican regimes had vested their hopes in this factory on their path to catching up with European industrialisation. The Ottomans, for their part, failed. This failure served as political capital for the republican Turks, who staked their ambitious industrialisation policy on the promise of transforming the semi-colonial Ottoman socioeconomic and geographic structure into a sovereign and autarkic nation-state. The Bakırköy Cloth Factory, together with three other old Ottoman and newly built state factories, would come to symbolise that transformation.

The empirical core of this book consists of an analysis of labour relations at a single state factory. Yet it has much more to say, by implication, not only about early republican Turkey, but also about nation-building and industrialisation in late-latecomer economies. Late Ottoman and early republican Turkey offers a unique opportunity to unpack the peripheral industrialisation and political economy of development because it serves as a critical juncture where political regime change and industrial development ideals intertwine. By placing these two processes within and against their wider historico-geographical field, this book elucidates the diverse array of international and domestic forces that shaped the political economy of underdevelopment, nation-building, and working-class politics in republican Turkey.

In writing this book, my aim is to strip etatism of its celebratory excess and highlight the critical role of nation-building in the construction of a new labour regime. In the Shadow of War and Empire is concerned with how workers, who were recategorised from imperial subjects to citizens, lived and worked through this transformation, struggling to be heard amid the thunder of nationalist developmentalism. The story of Turkish industrial relations in the 1930s and 1940s is reflective of many broader economic, political, and social trends in republican Turkey. Yet this is a largely neglected history, and one which has considerable wider significance for our understanding of the many meanings of work and working-class politics in the development of modern Turkey.

1 The Story: From Economic Colonialism to Economic Nationalism

It would not be inaccurate to describe the atmosphere of policymaking in the first years of the republic as “the urge to have done with empire.” The speed of the republican state’s superstructural and legislative reforms in the 1920s struck the international community as remarkable. Things were much slower in the economic realm though, because of the imperial commitments inherited from the latter part of the nineteenth century. The temporary economic provisions of the Treaty of Lausanne (1923), with regard to the Ottoman debt and customs tariffs in particular, hampered state capacity to assume the role of an autonomous policymaker. To begin with, this entailed Turkey relinquishing her right over the regulation of its trade regime and monetary policy. In addition to its massive international debt, the country was suffering in the face of the physical destruction of warfare and the financial and human cost of the population exchange with Greece, which meant, among other things, the loss of a significant portion of its skilled urban labour force. Despite its efforts, the republican regime was unable to reduce its dependency on the early industrialised economies during the first years of its existence.8

Then came the shock of the Great Depression. Turkey was one of the primary-goods producing countries hit hardest by the deflation that followed the 1929 crash. The vulnerability of the Turkish economy revealed that legal and cultural reforms were not enough to banish the Ottoman past to oblivion. The regime had already set up a temporal dichotomy between the Ottoman past and the republican present thanks to the superstructural changes. Following the global capitalist crisis, this dichotomy now shifted to the realm of economic policy, positioning factory-based industrialisation as the key symbolic site for revolutionary vigour and radical change. By the early 1930s, the state elite and middle-class intellectuals were becoming increasingly attuned to the depiction of the Ottoman economy as a colonial dependency controlled by European foreign interests. They argued that sustained industrialisation was the only way to transform the economic geography of a semi-colonised empire into a robust national economic entity.9

Perhaps the clearest expression of this came from a pro-government journalist, who resorted to racialised images of slave labour and Asian colonialism to describe the condition of the young republic. Prior to etatism, he lamented, Turkish cotton was “only as worthy as a Negro’s sweat.” But hope reigned by the end of the 1930s, he argued, as each rotation of the spindles erodes “part of our Asianness.”10 By the middle of the decade, industrialisation and economic nationalism would become key issues in Kemalist modernisation. The image of the belching industrial smokestacks, referred to “Atatürk’s minarets” by a group of foreign experts, dominated the political and intellectual landscape to an extent that is difficult to imagine in the present-day era of deindustrialisation.11 The project of modernisation was now synonymous with industrialisation, and the image of the factory embodied the republic’s eagerly anticipated future.

The distasteful memory of the Ottoman external debt, financial deficit, and dependence on European industrial technology and skills intensified the rush to construct a manufacturing industry that would both lighten the import burden and develop the essential basic elements of industrial management: adequate capital resources, competent management, skilled labour, and a responsive internal market for the later stages of industrialisation. The Kemalist leadership claimed that Turkey had no more time to lose; she needed to move fast to overcome the centuries-long inertia and catch up with Western industrial modernity. A desire to accelerate history and sweat out the lingering poison of the Ottoman influence underscored policymaking. The first five-year industrial plan reflected that sense of urgency, and, similarly to the import substitution industrialisation attempts that would be planned in later decades, focused on the manufacture of previously imported simple consumer goods for which internal markets and local raw materials existed and labour-intensive production methods could be employed.

The result was successful. The implementation of the industrial plan began in 1934 and, by the end of the decade, Turkey was already producing basic consumption goods that had previously been imported. Industry’s contribution to gross national product increased from 11.4 per cent between 1923 and 1929 to 16.9 per cent between 1933 and 1939.12 Large-scale government investment together with infusions of private capital resulted in a great expansion of the textile, cement, and sugar industries, as well as the creation of certain new ones such as paper, glass, rayon, iron, and steel. The index of physical output of medium-scale and large-scale industry increased from thirty-five in 1930 to one hundred in 1939, and the overall index of industrial output increased from sixty-four in 1938 to 115 in 1950. By the end of the 1930s, dependence on textile and foodstuff imports had fallen, while the share of capital goods had increased from 14.5 per cent to 37.2 per cent of total imports.13 The government also managed to repay a good proportion of its external debt, and attain a balanced budget.14 In 1945, the state was employing more than 100,000 workers in its factories. Five years later, this figure had reached 150,000, that is, fifteen per cent of the almost one million workers in manufacturing out of a total population of 12.6 million.15

Shortly before the government’s second industrial plan, which aimed to expand and roll out state industries, the shadow of another war would extend across the world.16 Turkey did not participate in the war, but the country nevertheless suffered severely amid the pressures on the global war economy. Industrial output decreased during the early years of the war as a result of intense shortages of imported machinery and spare parts as well as the toll that military conscription took on the already instable labour supply. In face of the fifty per cent fall in wheat production, the government initially tried to intervene through price controls, but abandoned this path in 1942. A hike in prices followed, resulting in a thirty per cent decrease in real wages.17 In the pages to follow, the reader will encounter state workers describing their impoverishment during the war years. Meanwhile, the formation of the wartime black market economy and widespread smuggling gave rise to the social category of war profiteers.

Private industrialists, who had accumulated a sizeable amount of capital thanks to wartime inflation, threw their weight behind a rival, more pro-business political party formed by a rrp splinter group. It was baptised the Democrat Party (Demokrat Parti, hereafter the dp), as a direct criticism of rrp rule.18 Etatism, which by 1945 had enveloped all major fields of the economy, represented one of the major lines of division between the Democrat Party and the chp, and, as such, came under increasing scrutiny. At the same time, the emergent and profoundly different postwar politico-economic order forced the chp to drop its long-standing policy of protectionism. The tensions of the Cold War developed quickly and intensely in Turkey, the furthest geographical outpost of the non-communist world. With an eye to admission to the new international organisations, and under pressure from Soviet territorial demands, the country came under the increasing influence of the North Atlantic coalition-in-the-making. To qualify for International Monetary Fund membership and to benefit from the Marshall Plan, the government initiated a major shift in economic policy involving devaluation and a set of foreign trade liberalisation measures. Etatist priorities gave way to agricultural development and export promotion; state resources were diverted to infrastructural investments to expand markets, and foreign credit became an important financial resource.19 The tide had turned by the end of the 1940s, opening up a whole new chapter in republican Turkish history. In 1950, the chp lost power after twenty-seven years of uninterrupted rule. In the Shadow of War and Empire narrates this series of events, and analyses the historical outcomes as well as their impact on industrialisation in modern Turkey.

2 The Argument: Controlling Labour on and beyond the Shop Floor

If one side of the Janus face of state-led industrialisation as it developed in 1930s Turkey entailed a sense of anxious but hopeful urgency, the other side displayed pure fear. Rapid industrialisation meant the rapid growth of an industrial working class. This is where the Turkish ruling elite’s complicated relationship with Western modernity enters the equation, signifying both an ideal to catch up with and a dark example to avoid repeating at all costs. The rulers desired all that industrial modernity represented, except for the violent history of class strife and class struggle. In 1935, the economic affairs minister assured the nation that Turkey’s shortcut to industrial modernity was safe because the policymakers knew the bumpy roads that the industrialised countries had taken all too well.20 He held up the 1936 Labour Code, which was modelled on Italian fascist legislation of 1935, as the strongest evidence of that “wisdom” and assured the public that it would “clear away the clouds of class consciousness once and for all.”21

From the very beginning, and although industrial employment remained modest up until the 1950s, Turkish industrialists acted out of fear of “the dark side” of industrialisation, that is, its potential to spread subversive ideologies. It was this fear that propelled the ruling elite to act as if it faced a large, militant, and organised industrial labour force, and to subdue the language and politics of class under the language and politics of the nation. Two interrelated factors came to their rescue here: the timing of industrialisation and etatism as a republican constitutional principle. Together, they fuelled a nationalist narrative of industrial work, mobilising a work ethic that concealed the unequal and coercive relations of production and, thus, subordinating class divisions in service to the nation.

Throughout the early republican period, the ruling elite would refer to the legacy of the Independence War with searing intensity. If the Ottoman Porte, a synecdoche for the central government of the Ottoman Empire and named after the gate leading to the principal state departments in Istanbul, embodied a purely self-interested and disloyal ruler, the republican parliament embodied a selfless and patriotic leader who had proven his loyalty in the liberation struggle. As the temporal marker of that break, the memory of the Independence War was central to the nationalist ethics of sacrifice for the rapid reconstruction of the country. Industrialisation, according to this official historiography, meant a revered effort to reconstruct a country that no longer belonged to a privileged few but to the entire Turkish nation. The time was ripe to demand a patriotic effort in the form of work. An International Labour Office report from 1949 described two prevailing aspects of public opinion with respect to the labour question in Turkey: the sense of national unity generated by the independence movement and the distrust of labour based on often inaccurate knowledge of developments in other countries.22

By placing the state at the heart of the industrialisation drive, etatism built on the ideal of industrial labour as patriotic service. Combined with populism, etatism as a constitutional principle safeguarded the Turkish state against the infiltration of class interests, promising developmental benefits to the nation as a whole. This set the Turkish case apart from the well-known Latin American populism of the same period. While the latter rested on a cross-class coalition of workers and industrialists, the former either rejected the existence of class altogether or subsumed it under a supra-class state. It followed logically that etatism was a class-neutral and nationalistic development plan; it was a powerful political and ideological concept as much as a pragmatic economic policy. The government succeeded in institutionalising the concept of a neutral state above class that would intervene directly in the socioeconomic order to minimise foreign economic dependence, eliminate class inequality, and prevent the emergence of class-based politics. Under etatism, workers would come up against this ideal whenever they attempted to challenge both the external and internal regulation of labour. This effectively dismissed the exploited status of labour in public discussion.

But where did industrial workers belong in this official narrative? To borrow from Satish Deshpande’s work on Nehru’s socialism, Kemalist industrialisation imagined the “patriotic producer” at the heart of the nation, surrounded by the apparatus of state-led planning; Turkish state factories anteceded “the temples of modern India” by two decades.23 The myth and the reality of the Turkish revolution gave etatism the ideological legitimisation it needed to call upon workers without giving them a voice in the national polity. State factories became the centrepieces of postimperial nation-making, and state workers epitomised the ideal of the patriotic producer. In contrast to a private factory, where a profit-making ethos would dominate, a state factory was a thoroughly and openly politicised space where workers were expected to toil for the benefit of a developmentalist regime.

In the field of industrial relations, etatism, again in the official discourse, meant the replacement of colonial and exploitative industrial relations with modern and egalitarian ones. From the beginning of state-led industrialisation, labour protectionism was one of the most important elements of the narrative drawing a contrast between the empire and the republic. In the words of the first labour minister, the fundamental difference between the republican regime and “the previous periods of backwardness” was the recognition of the value of work and workers:

The mentality that looked down on workers shook our country to its core and has left it on verge of ruin. Representing an attempt at a new life, our republican regime considers it one of its main duties to provide the rights and dignity of workers … The Turkish worker is not a mere productive machine for us, but a citizen on whose health, safety, and dignity we place a great deal of care.24

His pride in Turkish labour policy was widely shared. The first director of the Bakırköy Factory under etatism confidently explained his managerial vision to a European visitor: “If we take care from the outset not to create an exploited proletariat, if we make our workers feel that this factory belongs to the state and, therefore, to them, and if we really keep all the doors open to them to advance—why shouldn’t we succeed?”25 After a visit to the Bakırköy Factory in 1945, a journalist claimed: “the worker finds a heaven at [state] factories.”26 Another journalist described workers at Bakırköy as “shining, happy, and proud people.”27 Throughout the period, and especially until the emergence of a labour press after 1946, such celebratory reporting abounded, setting out state factories as exemplary national workplaces that provide their workforce with superior social and economic citizenship rights and serve as a model for ideal industrial relations for the whole nation.

The state ideology of class harmony found its strongest expression in the institutionalisation of compulsory arbitration that, once again, combined the claim to the supra-class character of the Turkish state with the fear of class conflict. Compulsory arbitration made perfect sense to a prominent contemporary social policy expert, who argued that because the state, as the largest industrial employer, by definition protected the public interest, it would also protect the interests of workers.28 Turkey thus diverged from other contexts of state-led industrialisation, where the state intervened actively in the labour-management relationship, first to protect labour, and then, when labour grew too strong, to control it through compulsory arbitration and other methods of repression. The Turkish state had already “clipped the wings” of the labour movement quite effectively in the 1920s, that is, before the state-led industrialisation arrived in full force.29 In the absence of the right to strike and collective agreements, the state served as the dominant and decisive voice in industrial disputes. At the same time, it largely abstained from intervening in wage determination processes, where, despite the appearance of bureaucratic rules and regulations for state industries at least, individual contracts remained the exclusive instrument regulating employment relationships. In the 1930s, foreign experts criticised the lack of any consistent wage policy at state factories; by the mid-1950s, a prominent contemporary sociologist observed that wages at state factories were determined on the basis of “social justice and moral deliberation.”30 Although the 1936 Labour Code empowered the government to issue minimum wage rates, only a few of these were actually issued. The situation remained unchanged even after the emergence of a trade union movement because unions were not able to play an effective role in arbitration. Wages remained low, and productivity problems persisted.31 The employers’ solution to this, including the managers of state factories, was further work intensification.

The reality of shop-floor relations simply did not square with the contemporary representations of state factories and their workers. Neither does it tally with the descriptions of worker passivity found in various scholarly pieces on the period, writing that positions state action central to an analysis based mainly on state-produced archival material. Re-embedding agency at the workplace level is important for two reasons. First, under conditions of repressive industrialisation, where class-based organisations are banned, workplace resistance requires particular attention. Second, in workplaces where the state plays the role of both employer and regulator, connecting worker agency to state formation and nation-building is key to understanding the making of working-class citizenship.

The ideology of patriotic labour failed to a large extent on the shop floor for a number of reasons. In spite of nationalist propaganda, serious and chronic problems of poor efficiency and low productivity characterised the operations of state factories from the very beginning. As early as 1934, industrial policymakers, who were closely following developments in both Europe (especially Germany) and the Soviet Union, underlined the need to rationalise industrial production and sought the help of foreign experts to reorganise production and implement scientific methods of labour control. The renovation of the Bakırköy Factory in 1934 was therefore meant to signify a mentality change, from the simple financial control of industrial enterprises to the combination of rational work and patriotic labour.32 But the operation of the Bakırköy Factory, and other state factories for that matter, remained trapped between the bottlenecks of centralised planning and the reality on the shop floor. There was a considerable gap between formal planning and practical execution, pointing to the fact that Turkish planning and centralisation were open-ended processes rather than a top-down implementation as in other contexts of planned industrialisation.33

Foreign and local experts alike agreed that the problems facing Turkish industry went beyond technical issues of productivity. The two main problems for state factories were “the deep sickness” of skills shortages combined with the inefficiency of worker control. The micro-level study of industrial relations offered in this book reveals that a strictly authoritarian world of labour lay hidden behind the ceremonial façade of a scientifically managed, worker-friendly industrial landscape. Industrial managers resorted mainly to work intensification to increase productivity, relying heavily on the iron rule of the foreman on the shop floor. The foremen fell back on tight supervision, abuse, profanity, and threats in order to maintain or increase work effort. In 1943, a foreign expert referred to the operational basis of state textile factories as “the anxiety to increase production,” comprised of a lack of scientific labour control and a managerial mentality of getting the most out of the workers and the machines.34 Supporting evidence came in the 1950s from a local expert, who wrote that industrial policymakers had omitted to consider giving labour its fair share in the benefits of rationalisation in order to secure its cooperation.35 In the cacophony produced by nationalist pride and the anxiety of underdevelopment, redistribution remained a distant idea, and state workers toiled for low wages and for long hours under a regime of repressive industrial relations.

Various scholars have shown that state-led industrialisation was directed by the general logic of capital accumulation. Except for a brief period in the early 1930s, when the scope of active state involvement provoked intense conflict within the ruling bloc, industrial policymakers were largely in agreement that etatism meant a mixed economy in which state and private investment were complementary. By 1935, private enterprise was defined as the “basic idea” in the party programme. The state used the relative autonomy it enjoyed under etatism to develop the socioeconomic and institutional infrastructure required to expand the sources of capital accumulation and mechanisms of surplus extraction.36 Between 1932 and 1939, the total amount of private capital invested in industry increased by more than eighty-six per cent.37 By the beginning of the war, a prominent economic historian wrote, the country had already passed the critical first threshold on the difficult road to industrialisation, thanks to the increase in the rate of accumulation.38 In 1939, thirty-four per cent of all factories were in the hands of private industrialists. The process accelerated during the war years, taking the figure to forty-five per cent by 1945.39 Industrial workers came out of the war overworked, exhausted, and impoverished. Having seized the exceptional opportunity for profiteering, private capital emerged from the war years with unprecedented rates of accumulation achieved mainly through speculation and black-marketing.40 The burden of industrialisation fell on the peasants and the industrial workers.41

In the Shadow of War and Empire joins this critical chorus to expand on the point further. Etatism served as the “nursemaid” of Turkish capitalism by providing it with lucrative credit options, expanding the national market, increasing the available technology and know-how, and developing industrial labour and management skills; it also created a labour regime that accelerated, aided, and nurtured private capital accumulation.42 Based on a new state-sponsored ideology of industrial work that combined nationalism and the ideal of harmonious industrial relations, both at the workplace and the national levels, the 1935 party programme institutionalised the nascent nationalistic labour regime. The 1936 Labour Code, the 1938 Associations Act (Cemiyetler Kanunu), and the 1940 National Defence Act (Milli Korunma Kanunu) added to these restrictions. The emergent labour regime had long-term consequences for the structure of industrial relations in Turkey in the way that it would shape state, employer, and trade union policies in subsequent decades.

My argument is premised on there being more to labour control than the sphere of production. The labour market is a mental and cultural—as well as an economic— structure, where historical actors negotiate a socially and culturally desirable order. The articulation of state and cultural discourse plays a central part in the constitution of labour control regimes. Building on the discursive representations of a class-neutral state on the one hand, and of “the national economy” and the worker-citizen’s place in it on the other, etatism played a central role in shaping both the real and discursive contours of the labour regime. Industrial policymakers resorted to etatism to ideologically mobilise and motivate workers to commit their labour power to the process of industrialisation. Such discourses were not only at work in legislation pertaining to industrial relations; they were also embedded and integrated into the regimes of labour control at the workplace level. The regime’s perception of its industrial workforce affected the management of industrialisation both on the shop floor and at the commanding heights of the economy.

As the state tried to mould industrial class politics into nation-building, the rhetorical devices of history and public memory became a contested terrain where employers’ demands for a labour imbued with patriotic motives clashed with workers’ demands for their share in the fruits of national development. The workplace emerged in this process as a crucial site of struggle, where workers, managers, and industrial policymakers would act on particular hegemonic representations of class and national identities. Besides working time and wage payments—the two main sources of major struggle within capitalist production relations—workplace politics manifested themselves as a negotiation of power over the boundaries between the identities of class and nation. In the 1930s and 1940s, workers contested the national narrative of industrial work and its accompanying labour control regime. The subtle, yet pervasive, worker agency expressed, first, at the micro-scale of the workplace and, then, in the trade union movement culminated in the rising tide of worker militancy in the 1960s and 1970s.

3 The Historiography: Industrial Workplace in Global Labour History43

A narrative of crisis had pervaded the discipline of labour history for more than two decades by the time I joined the field in the mid-2000s.44 This sense of a crisis was a response first and foremost to the socio-political problems of the 1980s. Two of these problems directly concerned the field of labour history. First, the argument that the “forward march of labour” had been halted cast doubt on the political primacy of working-class movements.45 Second, the very idea of work as the cornerstone of modern society was coming under intense critical scrutiny.46 Although unspecified, the category of work at stake here was industrial work, as evident in the term coined by social scientists to describe the new social order: post-industrial. Manufacturing had little contemporary resonance, they contended, and the once-emphasised industrial working class was now a marginal phenomenon.

One prominent approach that developed as a response to the perceived crisis of labour history was that of global labour history. By questioning an agenda that was seen as focusing on male workers in industry and other large-scale operations, global labour history broadened the geographical and thematic foci of traditional labour history. As research on non-industrial societies outside Western Europe and North America proliferated, labour historians began to transcend the traditional dichotomies between free and unfree labour, paid and unpaid work, and formally and informally organised workers.47

But what happened to the study of the industrial workplace when labour history found a new home? As the steady fragmentation of work and workplaces induced historians to explore previously neglected categories of workers, the potential of the industrial workplace for understanding the workings and logic of capitalism ceased to impress. In their efforts to counterbalance the disproportionate focus on industrial workers and the industrial workplace, labour historians this time relegated industrial work to the margins of the discipline and de-centred the workplace as a site of value production, exploitation, and class. Leon Fink observed that the new insights of labour history were coming at a cost of certain blinders, with the marginalisation of industrial labour in the global labour history framework being one of them.48

The move away from the historical study of industrial work and the industrial workplace is problematic in two ways. First, in the last two decades or so, factories have received attention almost exclusively at times of crises, such as the Rana Plaza collapse, the Foxconn suicides, and the liquidation of large public-sector companies in developing countries. But, in a world awash with manufactured goods, factories have not disappeared. Nor have they lost their relevance to capitalism. On the contrary, they remain significant sites of employment that are crucial to capitalism. The relocation of industrial production has created more factory jobs in developing economies without entirely destroying them in the developed world. Moreover, the tide seems to have turned at the level of economic policy, as evident from Donald Trump’s promise to revive American industry, former British chancellor George Osborne’s aspiration for “a Britain carried aloft by the march of the makers,” and India’s Narendra Modi’s “Make in India” slogan for his development agenda. More recently, the technological “reshoring” of manufacturing jobs has been on the agenda for industrial capitalists. And then there is the capital flight taking unexpected directions. For example, the Taiwanese multinational company Foxconn established workshops in Central and Eastern Europe, a region which has become the electronics industry’s second-tier global location, just behind East Asia.49 The 2019 Netflix hit documentary American Factory—and the first film produced by Barack and Michelle Obama’s production company—tells the story of a Chinese auto-glass manufacturing company opening a division in a shuttered General Motors factory near Dayton, Ohio, in 2016. Last but not least, companies within the service sector (call centres) and logistics and distribution (warehouses) have adopted the factory as a model of production, where workers are highly regimented and their activities constantly measured against metric performance standards, provoking arguments that they constitute present-day “Satanic mills.”50 Overall, these developments suggest that the factory’s “invisibility” in both current and historical agendas is less an outright disappearance and more a matter of marginalisation and disqualification.51

Second, the body of scholarship on the industrial workplace is highly unevenly distributed between the global north and the global south because of inequality in the means of research production, including but not limited to the complex politics of archival work. Within global relations of unequal academic exchange, local processes of state and class formation have shaped national historiographies.52 By the time the factory and industrial work ceased to impress historians with its potential for understanding capitalism, industrial workplaces in much of the global south had been explored in only the most peripheral way.53 Though it is true that the extent of scholarship on industrial labour is significantly smaller in contexts outside Western Europe and North America (the socialist scholarship on the industrial workplace, especially after 1945, should of course be included here), the difference is not only a matter of quantity. The subject has taken different paths in “the north” and “the south.” Even if the historical shift to the industrial workplace was systemic and global in character, it was definitely not uniform or linear. Historically, capitalism created a variety of labour relations both within and between industrial workplaces.

To begin with, and mostly based on a series of global antinomies on working-class formation such as traditional versus modern, co-optation versus autonomy, and resistance versus integration, history written outside Europe has mostly been “the historiography of ‘(not) yet,’ of absences.”54 Similarly to the problematisation of the absent bourgeoisie as “the collective hero of western civilisation” in Soviet historiography, or the “dominance-without-hegemony” thesis in Indian historiography, the dominance of state over society and the implications of a missing native bourgeoisie have been most prevailing paradigms in Ottoman and Turkish historiography.55 In India, for example, historians cited the weakness of capitalist development and the persistence of “pre-modern” non-class loyalties as evidence for the unthinkability of a working class, let alone a class-conscious working class.56 In the same vein, when I first expressed my interest in the labour history of the early republican period, a prominent Turkish historical sociologist asked me whether there even existed a working class worthy of study at all.

The enduring resilience of the law and the state in studies on Turkey’s working-class history misses the complexity of labour-state relations. As a latecomer to issues being raised by social and transnational history, scholarship in Turkey has remained largely state-centred, policy-oriented, and insular. Reduced to the prey of state ideology and manipulation, the working class is usually presented as an ideal construct at the service of state ideology, whereas the state is conceptualised as a more or less autonomous bureaucratic apparatus.57 Because labour historians have tended to reduce class formation to stages of economic development, they have rarely passed through the gate of the industrial workplace to analyse the social relations in production, including regimes of labour control, changes in the labour process and technology, shop-floor cultures, and the production of gender, ethnic, and racial difference on the shop floor.58 Historians have mistaken state and management discourse and objectives for what actually happened inside the workplace because they viewed the industrial workplace as the derivative of external orientations to work rather than as a source of conflict and identity. Because working-class formation and political development seem to have occurred in a sphere external to the workplace, the rank-and-file politics of workers and their mentalities, identities, and everyday experiences have virtually escaped scholarly attention.59

The challenge facing historians of industrial labour, especially in the global south, is to take the recent historiographical and theoretical insights and bring them to bear on the industrial workplace. By interweaving the history of the industrial workplace with questions of national and transnational movements of labour and capital, memory, state policy, and national ideology, we can view history in our own regions in a new light. The economic, social, and political transformations of the industrial workplace have not only mirrored but also shaped national and global shifts; a study of its history presents a way of approaching broader historical processes while engaging with specifically local questions.

We are lucky to have a base to build on for a more totalising and less particularistic history of the industrial workplace. Industrial workplace-based research in labour history and in fields adjacent to labour history have left behind a theoretically and empirically rich tradition. From the renowned American Hawthorne study within a social psychology framework in the 1920s and 1930s, to the anthropologically informed studies of factories in the 1940s, and the expansion of British industrial anthropology and sociology in the 1950s and 1960s, shop-floor studies have grown central to social theory.60 In the 1960s, autonomous Marxists coined the term “social factory” to explain how the capital accumulation process escapes the confines of the factory and extends into society as a whole.61 In the 1970s, labour process theory revitalised sociological studies of work by focusing on how the indeterminacy of labour power generated struggle and resistance on the shop floor.62 It became commonplace for researchers of industrial workplaces to challenge abstract conceptions of workplace conflict and class struggle, and to conceptualise industrial conflict beyond its overt, organised expression and incorporate it into their analyses of the daily experiences of workers and their representatives, composing a far more complex picture of the past.

Scholars theorising the workplace in historical studies joined this concerted effort, drawing on labour process theory and social history. Arguing that the worker’s worldview was formed above all at the point of production, they called for the study of workers within the workplace itself, the site where “working people and the capitalists confronted each other [and] the labour process is actualized” and where “the theory and practice of industrial relations strategies meet, founder, are successful or modified.”63 Analyses at this level offer a view into the nitty-gritty of formal and informal mechanisms of political mediation on the shop floor.

Recent studies have begun to recognise the centrality of the workplace and shop-floor organisation to an understanding not only of working-class experience and the process of intersectional identity formation, but also of wider social developments. They have conceptualised the industrial workplace beyond a local and inward-looking unit, to incorporate different angles beyond the exclusive focus on labour relations. Through new interpretative lenses, they have addressed a range of questions such as the construction and reconstruction of social identities in relation to the experience of work, the production of social difference both in relation to labour and social practices, and the discourses around it.64 There has also been an upsurge in interest in the anthropological study of the industrial workplace. Recent work on the anthropology of industrial labour has focused on the experience of flexible work on fragmented shop floors, that is, the unequal employment status between regular and casual, or between company and contract workers. Underlining how Taylorist and flexible forms of production are recombined and reconnected on the same shop floor, anthropologists have analysed labour relations among workers enjoying different work statuses and benefits while working in the same industrial workplace, sometimes doing the exact same job. Anthropologists have also underlined the intricate connections between the local workplace and global markets. By linking localised centres of production with wider global relationships and forces, they have shown how chains of production and consumption relate to industrial relations.65 The time is ripe for a cross-fertilisation between history and other disciplines, from anthropology to critical organisational studies and geography, and to explore the industrial workplace as a key place to challenge the models of a linear and uniform progress of capitalism and to analyse its combined and uneven development across time and space.

This book joins the recent efforts to open up the national histories of labour based on modernisation theories by attending to the worker’s concrete experience at the point of production. In exploring the complex dimensions of class as a lived experience and structured determination, it strives to overcome the divide between the micro level of the production floor and the macro level of state policy, doing history “from the bottom up, all the way to the top.”66 It treats the Bakırköy Factory not as the background to the story, a closed and inward-looking unit behind-the-scenes, but as a “contact zone,” that is, a seemingly static locality made up of circulations of capital, labour, and industrial expertise, as well as the politico-economic visions of different state regimes.67 Both in history and in cinema, the global perspective in any close-up is implicit, argues Carlo Ginzburg.68 The close-ups in this book focus on workers’ everyday practices that are replete with agency, and I build on them to reconnect worker agency to the wider societal structures it is embedded in.

4 The Book: Sources, Themes, and Organisation

In the Shadow of War and Empire offers a broad variety of perspectives and voices through which to examine both the official and celebratory narratives as well as the critical counternarratives on etatism. Throughout the book, the reader will hear from bureaucrats, intellectuals, foreign and local industrial experts, employers, managers, and, last but not least, workers themselves. To present these diverse voices, I draw on a broad range of sources, including state documents, inspection reports, travel writing, memoirs, workers’ files, oral interviews, and periodicals.

Turkey’s relatively weak archival infrastructure and its historically modest levels of popular literacy have tempted scholars of labour to opt for textual analyses of the discourses generated by dominant groups. This has impeded the pressing task of undoing the elite-centred historiography. Materials that allow us to see and understand what workers were doing and thinking, or data of any kind on the actual work process, are hard to find in Turkey. As are worker voices on how they experienced work, how they made sense of their lives and the wider forces operating in society, and how they lived with the demands and constraints of industrial labour. For the brief period of trade unionism covered here, there are virtually no documents actually produced by the unions. As a whole, the scant, scattered, and mostly normative nature of historical material has been a major constraint in writing this book. Partly to overcome this difficulty, I dynamically move between different scales of analysis. In order to demonstrate the complex and varied ways in which nation-building and industrialisation interacted on and off the factory floor, I have pieced together Bakırköy workers’ life trajectories from slim and sketchy material, highlighting the embeddedness of their experiences and the choices available to them in the larger context of hierarchical relations of power and domination. Although I have not been afraid to indulge in reasoned and informed speculation or comment, I have tried not only to explicitly note such instances but also to keep them to a minimum.

Since they present workers’ voices most clearly, a few words on the workers’ files are warranted. In the mid-2000s, the workers’ files were still at the factory site. In my first attempt to view them, I was told they had been lost. After spending more than a year going back and forth between government offices, I learnt that they had become dark archives, meaning that they lay uncatalogued and inaccessible to researchers in the basement of the Republican Archives. Six months of persistence later, I gained extremely limited access to specific records following a process of personal negotiation. During the two months of my permitted access, I was able to request files based on limited information (namely, name, staff number, birth place, and date) on Excel sheets covering all state workers. Under these circumstances, finding the file of a worker who worked in the Bakırköy Factory in the 1930s or 1940s felt like winning the lottery. Not being allowed to photograph or copy the documents, I took handwritten notes. I spent several years pestering the national archives for further access to these files, but to no avail.

This severely limited archival access served to silence the voices of child workers. They were certainly there, and they were many. But their voices could not be found in the archives. With female workers, I had slightly more success, but almost all of the very few files that belonged to women were empty, except for their initial employment forms. Despite my efforts to recruit alternative sources through which women could speak, I could not overcome the gendered silences of documentation and history. At this point, I can only hope for further studies that investigate in more detail how class and gender interacted on the shop floor.

The book comprises two parts. Part 1 covers the state strategies of industrialisation, first, in the mid-nineteenth-century Ottoman Empire and, then, in republican Turkey. From the construction of the Bakırköy Factory in the 1840s to the implementation of etatism in the 1930s, it focuses on the political economy and macro processes of peripheral industrialisation. The central themes here are postimperial state discourses, labour legislation, spatiality of development, and local labour markets. With Part 2, we enter the gates of the Bakırköy Factory, but without losing sight of the relations of production, the external regulation of labour, and the worker experience outside the workplace. The experience-near analysis of the lived reality of state-led industrialisation on the shop floor here builds on the macro processes described in Part 1. By reducing the scale of historical analysis, I redirect the reader’s gaze toward the dense textures of workers’ everyday lives, social relationships, and political agency. Relationships and bargaining at the point of employment, gender relations on the shop floor, and the development of the trade union movement are among the central themes I explore.

The general approach adopted in terms of organisation of this book has been that of narrative analysis. The chapters follow a chronological order. The first chapter locates the politico-economic underpinnings of 1930s Turkish state-led industrialisation within the nineteenth-century peripheralisation of the Ottoman economy. In order to ground the story in place and time, it starts with Ottoman efforts to catch up with European manufacturing by constructing an industrial complex they proudly crowned the “Turkish Manchester.” The chapter presents a multi-level analysis of the political economy of Ottoman underdevelopment, the urban industrial geography of Istanbul, the financially and industrially prominent Armenian Dadian family, the technology and technical expertise transfer from Europe, and the multi-ethnic character of the Ottoman industrial workforce. An analysis of how this history was rewritten completely during the republican period sets the tone for the remainder of the book.

Chapter 2 finds Turkey in the midst of the Independence War, and follows her through the first decade of her struggles and ambitions. The central focus of this chapter is the diverse array of international and domestic forces that brought about the policy change from an open economy in the 1920s to a mixed economy of protectionism and etatism in the 1930s. Besides the politico-economic and policy determinants of state-led industrialisation, I also attend to the intra-elite conflicts, specifically the politics of foreign industrial expertise, the debate on the institutional framework of industrialisation, and the multiple failed attempts to enact a Turkish labour code. The winning party in these class conflicts within the state apparatus would go on to direct etatism as a capitalist project of industrialisation with a clear vision of class relations in the coming years.

But what was the territorial logic that lay behind state-led industrialisation? Chapter 3 starts with this question, and explains how the Turkish state elite desperately tried to undo the uneven geographical development that was left behind by the Ottoman economy under the domination of foreign capital. The spatial configuration of development thinking reflected the postimperial anxieties associated with transforming Turkey into an economically and culturally integrated nation-state. Together with a nationalised and expanded railway network, industrial site selection in interwar Turkey was part of a state strategy to achieve national consolidation and effective statehood. This chapter offers an important correction to the treatment of state industries as a unified entity by examining the differences between the old industrial centres and the new industrial sites in terms of local labour market dynamics. The historically uneven spatial development of capitalism produced considerably divergent outcomes in terms of labour recruitment and stability, as well as the conditions of labour reproduction. It was local rather than national forces that shaped labour market outcomes, especially with regards to its gender dynamics.

Shop-floor industrial relations sit at the centre of the analysis in Chapter 4. I take issue with the prevalent arguments on state workers’ working and living conditions in the 1930s and 1940s, attending to the physical conditions of production, the factory administrative structure, employment and wage policy, labour control strategies, social provisions, and housing problems. This chapter brings the disjuncture between ideological prescription and everyday practice to the fore by examining the micro-physics of power. The failed attempt at rationalising production, repressive shop-floor management practices, and isolated and individualised worker resistance are the main themes.

Building on the extended histories of workers’ shop floor experiences through their petitions, Chapter 5 depicts the factory as a space of everyday work charged with political meaning, and traces the day-to-day conflicts and compromises that took place on the shop floor in the 1940s. The Turkish state factory, like any other industrial workplace under capitalism, was a contested terrain where norms were negotiated and redefined. A two-way struggle between labour and management, however unequal the terms, over the drawing of lines of authority characterised daily interactions on the shop floor. Midway into the 1940s, a significant change occurred in the direct manifestation of class relationships over the control of the job and the line of authority. This chapter explains that change through a study of the links between the political system, industrial legislation, and the emergence of new patterns of industrial conflict.

With chapter 6, we enter the fast-changing world of workers in postwar Turkey to track down the rise of labour as a political category. Focusing on the early trade union movement, I build on the premise that workplace relations and working-class politics are not merely expressions of structural class positions, and argue that worker subjectivity contains shifting and contradictory positions that cannot be understood without paying due attention to labour relations on the shop floor. I specifically follow the life trajectories of two trade unionists during the 1950s who adopted two different insider’s critiques of the mainstream political direction taken by the union movement, and paid for their political choices. Their life stories reveal the multiple working-class political positions that were extinguished or submerged.

I now invite the reader to a century-long industrial walk in Istanbul. We will set off with enthusiastic Ottoman industrialists and their curious but cautious European visitors, continue with ambitious republican policymakers and idealistic factory managers, and end with disillusioned but increasingly determined worker-citizens. An industrial workplace overlooking the Marmara Sea, which once lay outside the city walls but was later incorporated into the city, will be our vantage point to look upon this action-packed history.

1

Peter Hudis, ed., The Complete Works of Rosa Luxemburg, vol. 1 (London: Verso, 2013), 113–114.

2

Andre Gunder Frank, “The Development of Underdevelopment,” in Latin America: Underdevelopment or Revolution, ed. Andre Gunder Frank (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1969); Colin Leys, “Underdevelopment and Dependency: Critical Notes,” Journal of Contemporary Asia 7, no. 1 (1977), 92–107.

3

Eric Hobsbawm, Industry and Empire (Suffolk: Penguin, 1969), 210; Andre Gunder Frank, Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America: Historical Studies of Chile and Brazil (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1967), 149.

4

Korkut Boratav, “Büyük Dünya Bunalımı İçinde Türkiye’nin Sanayileşme ve Gelişme Sorunları: 1929–1939” in Tarihsel Gelişimi İçinde Türkiye, ed. Orhan Kurmuş et al. (Ankara: Makina Mühendisleri Odası, 1977), 3–4.

5

Clark Kerr, John T. Dunlop, Frederick H. Harbison, and Charles A. Myers, Industrialism and Industrial Man: The Problem of Labour and Management in Economic Growth (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1960), 271; Zivi Yehuda Hershlag, Turkey: The Challenge of Growth (Leiden: e.j. Brill, 1968), 74; Gunnar Myrdal, Asian Drama: An Inquiry into the Poverty of Nations (New York: Pantheon Books, 1972), 248–249; Charles Issawi, De-industrialization and Re-industrialization in the Middle East Since 1800,” International Journal of Middle Eastern Studies 12, no. 4 (1980), 474; Korkut Boratav, Kemalist Economic Policies and Étatism,” in Atatürk: Founder of a Modern State, eds. Ali Kazancıgil and Ergun Özbudun (London: C. Hurst & Company, 1981), 175; Zivi Yehuda Hershlag, The Contemporary Turkish Economy (London: Routledge, 1988), ix; Haldun Gülalp, Capitalism and the Modern Nation-State: Rethinking the Creation of the Turkish Republic,” Journal of Historical Sociology 7, no. 2 (1994), 155; Alfred Bonne, Studies in Economic Development (London: Routledge, 1998), 107–108; Haldun Gülalp, The Eurocentrism of Dependency Theory and the Question of ‘Authenticity’: A View from Turkey,” Third World Quarterly 19, no. 5(1998), 954; Alan Richards, John Waterbury, Melani Cammett, and Ishac Diwan, A Political Economy of the Middle East (Boulder: Westview Press, 2013), 239; M. Erdem Özgür and Eyüp Özveren, “Turkey’s Attempt to Break the Fetters Before the Ladder was Kicked Away, 1929–1947,” in Political Economy of Development in Turkey 1838-Present, eds. Emre Özçelik and Yonca Özdemir (London: Palgrave Macmillan, 2022), 113.

6

Selim Deringil, “The Ottoman Origins of Kemalist Nationalism: Namık Kemal to Mustafa Kemal,” European History Quarterly 23 (1993), 165.

7

Hikmet Kıvılcımlı, Türkiye İşçi Sınıfının Sosyal Varlığı (Istanbul: Bozkurt Matbaası, 1935), 51.

8

Çağlar Keyder, The Definition of a Peripheral Economy: Turkey 1923–1929 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981), vii; Haldun Gülalp, “Patterns of Capital Accumulation and State-Society Relations in Turkey,” Journal of Contemporary Asia 15, no. 3 (1985), 334; Zvi Yehuda Hershlag, The Contemporary Turkish Economy (London; New York: Routledge, 1988), 1–3; Feroz Ahmad, The Making of Modern Turkey (London: Routledge, 1993), 94; Korkut Boratav, Türkiye İktisat Tarihi (Istanbul: Gerçek Yayınevi, 1993), 37; Korkut Boratav, “İktisat Tarihi (1908–1980)” in Türkiye Tarihi 4: Çağdaş Türkiye 1908–1980, ed. Sina Akşin (Istanbul: Cem Yayınevi, 2008), 311.

9

Vedat Nedim Tör, “Müstemleke İktisadiyatından Millet İktisadiyatına,” Kadro 1, no. 1 (1932), 8–11; Bilsay Kuruç, Belgelerle Türkiye İktisat Politikası, 1933–1935, vol. 2 (Ankara: Ankara Üniversitesi Yayınları, 1993), 175, 269.

10

Cemal Kutay, “Değişme,” Ulus, 18 May 1939.

11

Max Weston Thornburg, Graham Spry, and George Soule, Turkey: An Economic Appraisal (New York: The Twentieth Century Fund, 1949), 105–106.

12

Boratav, “İktisat Tarihi (1908–1980),” 328; Korkut Boratav, Kemalist Economic Policies and Étatism,” in Atatürk: Founder of a Modern State, eds. Ali Kazancıgil and Ergun Özbudun (London: C. Hurst & Company, 1981), 179.

13

United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, The Development of Manufacturing Industry in Egypt, Israel and Turkey (New York: United Nations, 1958), 17; Bonne, Studies in Economic Development, 108; Zivi Yehuda Hershlag, Introduction to the Modern Economy of the Middle East (Leiden: Brill, 1964), 198; Şevket Pamuk, Uneven Centuries: Economic Development of Turkey Since 1820 (Princeton: Princeton University Press 2018), 278; William Hale, “Ideology and Economic Development in Turkey 1930–1945,” Bulletin British Society for Middle Eastern Studies 7, no. 2 (1980), 108.

14

Yakup Kepenek and Nurhan Yentürk, Türkiye Ekonomisi (Istanbul: Remzi Kitabevi, 1994), 59, 61; Pamuk, Uneven Centuries, 189–190; Boratav, “Kemalist Economic Policies,” 179.

15

Ahmet Özeken, “Türkiye Sanayiinde İşçiyi Barındırma Problemi,” Sosyal Siyaset Konferansları Dergisi 3 (1950), 104; United States Bureau of Labour Statistics, Summary of the Labour Situation in Turkey (Washington: International Cooperation Administration Office of Labour Affairs, 1956),15; Ahmet Makal, “Türkiye’nin Sanayileşme Sürecinde İşgücü Sorunu, Sosyal Politika ve İktisadi Devlet Teşekkülleri: 1930’lu ve 1940’lı Yıllar,” Toplum ve Bilim 92 (2002), 38.

16

Şevket Pamuk, “Political Economy of Industrialization in Turkey,” merip Reports 93 (1981).

17

Boratav, “İktisat Tarihi (1908–1980),” 335; Pamuk, “Industrialization in Turkey,” 26.

18

Osman Okyar, “The Concept of Etatism,” Economic Journal 75, no. 297 (1965), 106.

19

Kepenek and Yentürk, Türkiye Ekonomisi, 84, 122; Pamuk, Uneven Centuries, 206; Gülalp, “Patterns of Capital Accumulation,” 336; İlhan Tekeli and Selim İlkin, Savaş Sonrası Ortamında 1947 Türkiye İktisadi Kalkınma Planı (Ankara: odtü Yayınları, 1974), 15–24.

20

Kuruç, Belgelerle 2, 269.

21

Recep Peker, the General Secretary of the Republican People’s Party, speaking during parliamentary discussions on the labour code. tbmm Tutanak Dergisi (Records of the Grand National Assembly), 8 June 1936, Session 5, vol. 12, Meeting no. 75, 83–84.

22

International Labour Office, “Labour Problems in Turkey,” Report of a Mission of the International Labour Office (Geneva: ILO, 1950), 17.

23

Charles A. Myers, Labour Problems in the Industrialization of India (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1958), 7; Satish Deshpande, “Imagined Economies: Styles of Nation-Building in Twentieth Century India,” Journal of Arts and Ideas 25, no. 26 (1993), 25; Srirupa Roy, Beyond Belief: India and the Politics of Postcolonial Nationalism (Durham: Duke University Press, 2007), 134; Jonathan Parry and Christian Strümpell, “On the Desecration of Nehru’s ‘Temples’: Bhilai and Rourkela Compared,” Economic and Political Weekly 43, no. 19 (2008), 47–57.

24

Sadi lrmak, “Yurdun En Büyük İşçi Sendikası Kömür Havzasında Kuruldu,” Türk İşçisi, 12 April 1947.

25

Lilo Linke, Allah Dethroned: A Journey Through Modern Turkey (London: Constable and Co., 1937), 308.

26

Abidin Daver, “Bakırköy Fabrikasında,” Cumhuriyet, 19 November 1945.

27

Sedat Saip Altuğ, “Sümerbank Bakırköy Pamuklu Sanayii Müessesesi Yüz Yaşında,” Mensucat Meslek Dergisi 4, no. 1 (1951), 28–32.

28

Cahit Talas, İçtimai İktisat (Ankara: s.b.f. Yayınları, 1961), 298–299.

29

Kerr et al., Industrialism and Industrial Man, 92–93.

30

Ziyaeddin Fahri Fındıkoğlu, “Türkiye’de Sınai Sosyoloji Araştırmaları 1-Defterdar Fabrikası,” Feshane Mensucat Meslek Dergisi 2, no. 12 (1954), 393; Görkem Akgöz, “Experts, Exiles, and Textiles: German ‘Rationalisierung’ on 1930s Turkish Shop Floor,” International Review of Social History 66, no. 2 (2021).

31

ılo, “Labour Problems in Turkey,” 188; United States Bureau of Labour Statistics, Summary, 23; Kurthan Fişek, Devlete Karşı Grevlerin Kritik Tahlili (Ankara: Ankara Üniversitesi Siyasal Bilgiler Fakültesi Yayınları, 1969), 47; Toker Dereli, Aydınlar, Sendika Hareketi ve Endüstriyel İlişkiler Sistemi (Istanbul: Istanbul Üniversitesi İktisat Fakültesi Yayını, 1974), 88; Talas, İçtimai İktisat, 299.

32

Kuruç, Belgelerle 2, 269; “Başvekil Hz. Sümer Bank Fabrikalarını Tetkik Ettiler,” Cumhuriyet, 22 November 1933; “Yeni Daireleri Dün Açıldı,” Haber-Akşam Postası, 14 August 1934.

33

Stephen Kotkin, Magnetic Mountain: Stalinism as a Civilization (Oakland: University of California Press, 1997); Alina-Sandra Cucu, Planning Labour: Time and the Foundations of Industrial Socialism in Romania (New York: Berghahn, 2019).

34

Hösli, Bakırköy Bez Fabrikası Hakkında Rapor, 1943. Archival Collection of the Republic of Turkey Prime Ministry Supreme Audit Board.Amb. /Db.No: k.a./255.07.02.01.06.1241, 19.

35

Cahit Talas, “Verimliliğin Arttırılmasında Psikolojik ve Manevi Amiller,” Çalışma Vekâleti 1, no. 1 (1953), 98.

36

Fişek, Grevlerin Kritik Tahlili, 5; Yahya Sezai Tezel, “Turkish Economic Development 1923–1950: Policy and Achievements” (PhD diss., University of Cambridge, 1975), 171; İlhan Tekeli and Selim İlkin, Uygulamaya Geçerken Türkiye’de Devletçiliğin Oluşumu (Ankara: odtü İdari İlimler Fakültesi, 1982), 336; Berch Berberoğlu, Turkey in Crisis: From State Capitalism to Neo-colonialism (London: Zed Books, 1982), 58; Bilsay Kuruç, Mustafa Kemal Döneminde Ekonomi (Istanbul: Bilgi Yayınevi, 1987), 53; Kuruç, Belgelerle 2, 225; Boratav, Türkiye İktisat Tarihi, 57; Boratav, “İktisat Tarihi (1908–1980),” 325; Kepenek and Yentürk, Türkiye Ekonomisi, 70, 83–84; Pamuk, “Industrialization in Turkey,” 26; Galip Yalman, “The Turkish State and Bourgeoisie in Historical Perspective: A Relativist Paradigm or a Panapoly of Hegemonic Strategies?” in The Politics of Permanent Crisis; Class, Ideology and State in Turkey, eds. Neşecan Balkan and Sungur Savran (New York: Nova Science Publishers Inc., 2002), 29–30; Taha Parla and Andrew Davison, Corporatist Ideology in Kemalist Turkey: Progress or Order? (Syracuse: Syracuse University Press, 2004), 128; Gülten Kazgan, Türkiye Ekonomisinde Krizler (1929–2001), “Ekonomi Politik” Açısından bir İrdeleme (Istanbul: Bilgi Üniversitesi Yayınları, 2005), 78–81; Gülten Kazgan, Türkiye Ekonomisinde Krizler, 1929–2001, 81; Korkut Boratav, Türkiye’de Devletçilik, 2nd ed. (Ankara: İmge Kitabevi, 2017), 356–357; Richards et al., A Political Economy of the Middle East, 43, 178.

37

Fişek, Grevlerin Kritik Tahlili, 41.

38

Boratav, “Kemalist Economic Policies,” 186.

39

Mehmet Şehmus Güzel, “İkinci Dünya Savaşı Boyunca Sermaye ve Emek,” in Osmanlı’dan Cumhuriyet Türkiye’sine İşçiler, eds. Donald Quataert and Erik Jan Zürcher, trans. Cahide Ekiz (Istanbul: İletişim Yayınları, 1998), 221.

40

Gülalp, “Patterns of Capital Accumulation,” 335–336; Ali Yaşar Sarıbay, “The Democratic Party, 1946–1960,” in Political Parties and Democracy in Turkey, eds. Martin Heper and Jacob M. Landau (New York: i.b. Tauris, 1990), 120.

41

S.C. Wyatt, “Turkey: The Economic Situation and the Five-Years Plan,” International Affairs 13, no. 6 (1934), 833–834; Robert V. Kerwin, “Private Enterprise in Turkish Industrial Development,” Middle East Journal 5, no. 1 (1951), 27; Alec Alexander, “Turkey,“ in Economic Development: Analysis and Case Studies, eds. Adamantios Pepelasis, Leon Mears, and Irma Adelman (New York: Harper & Brothers Publishers, 1961), 475; David Waldner, State Building and Late Development (Ithaca: Cornell University Pres, 1999), 204–205; Pamuk, “Industrialization in Turkey,” 26; Barkey, The State and The Industrialisation, 5; Boratav, Türkiye İktisat Tarihi, 53–54; Boratav, “Kemalist Economic Policies,” 178; Korkut Boratav, Türkiye İktisat Tarihi 1908–2009 (Istanbul: Imge, 2003), 53–54, 79; Pamuk, Uneven Centuries, 189.

42

James M. Barker, The Economy of Turkey: An Analysis and Recommendations for A Development Program (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press, 1951), 161–162; Necdet Serin, “Industrialization Policy of Turkey Since 1923,” Ankara Üniversitesi sbf Dergisi 20, no. 2 (1965), 199; William Hale attributes the phrase “nursemaid of capitalism” to the economic affairs minister, Celal Bayar. See: William Hale, The Political and Economic Development of Modern Turkey (London: Croom Helm, 1981), 56.

43

I have formulated most of the ideas in this section in dialogue with the members of the working group Workplaces: Pasts and Presents (formerly known as Factory History) of the European Labour History Network (https://socialhistoryportal.org/elhn/wg-workplaces). See also Görkem Akgöz, Richard Croucher and Nicola Pizzolato, “Back to the Factory: The Continuing Salience of Industrial Workplace History,” Labor History 61, no. 1 (2020), 1–11.

44

Jeffrey Cox, “Labour History and the Labour Movement,” Journal of British Studies 25 (1986), 233–241; James Epstein, “Rethinking the Categories of Working-Class History,” Labour/Le Travail 18 (1986), 195–208; Charles Bergquist, “Labour History and Its Challenges: Confessions of a Latin Americanist,” The American Historical Review 98, no. 3 (1993), 757–764; Marcel van der Linden, ed., The End of Labour History? (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994); Laura L. Frader, “Dissent over Discourse: Labour History, Gender and the Linguistic Turn,” History and Theory 34, no. 3 (1995), 213–30; Geoff Eley and Keith Nield, “Farewell to the Working Class?” International Labour and Working-Class History 57, no. 1 (2000), 30.

45

Eric Hobsbawm, “The Forward March of Labour Halted?” Marxism Today 22, no. 9 (1978), 279–286; Gareth Stedman-Jones, Languages of Class: Studies in English Working Class History, 1832–1982, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983).

46

André Gorz, Farewell to the Working Class: An Essay on Post-Industrial Socialism (London: Pluto Press, 1982); Jeremy Rifkin, The End of Work: The Decline of the Global Labour Force and the Dawn of the Post-Market Era (New York: Tarcher, 1995).

47

Marcel van der Linden, Workers of the World: Essays toward a Global Labour History (Leiden: Brill, 2008); Marcel van der Linden, “Labour History Beyond Borders,” in Histories of Labour: National and International Perspectives, eds. Joan Allen, Alan Campbell, and John Mcllroy (Decatur: Merlin Press, 2010), 359–360; Lex Heerma Van Voss, “Whither Labour History? Histories of Labour: National and International Perspectives,” International Review of Social History 58, no. 1 (2013), 97–106.

48

Leon Fink, “The Great Escape: How a Field Survived Hard Times,” Labour: Studies in Working-Class History of the Americas 8, no. 1 (2011), 115.

49

Rutvica Andrijasevic and Devi Sacchetto, “China May be Far Away but Foxconn is On Our Doorstep,” accessed 5 June 2013, https://www.opendemocracy.net/en/china-may-be-far-away-but-foxconn-is-on-our-doorstep/; Rutvica Andrijasevic and Devi Sacchetto, “Made in the EU: Foxconn in the Czech Republic,” WorkingUSA: The Journal of Labour and Society 17 (2014).

50

Peter Bain and Phil Taylor, “Entrapped by the ‘Electronic Panopticon’? Worker Resistance in the Call Centre,” New Technology, Work and Employment 15, no. 1 (2000); Moritz Altenried, The Digital Factory: The Human Labor of Automation (Chicago: Chicago University Press, 2022).

51

Jackie Clarke, “Closing Moulinex: Thoughts on the Visibility and Invisibility of Industrial Labour in Contemporary France,” Modern & Contemporary France 19, no. 4 (2011).

52

Marcel van der Linden, “Labour History: The Old and the New and the Global,” African Studies 66, no. 2–3 (2007), 174; Gabriel Winant, Andrew Gordon, Sven Beckert, and Rudi Batzell, “Introduction: The Global e.p. Thompson,” International Review of Social History 61 (2016), 1.

53

It should be noted that significant differences in labour historiography exist in the global south. Latin America and South Africa, for example, saw a wave of historical studies on industrial labour in the 1970s. Interest in labour history preceded this wave by a decade due to the strong influence of the British university tradition. See: Marcel van der Linden, “The ‘Globalisation’ of Labour and Working-Class History and Its Consequences,” in The Global History of Work: Critical Readings: Vol. i: Work and Workers in Context, ed. Marcel van der Linden (London: Bloomsbury Publishing, 2019), 138–139.

54

van der Linden, “The ‘Globalization’ of Labour and Working-Class,” 142.

55

Şerif Mardin, “Center–Periphery Relations: A Key to Turkish Politics?” Daedalus 102 (1972), 169–191; A. J. Toynbee, “The Ottoman Empire’s Place in World History,” in The Ottoman State and Its Place in World History, ed. Kemal Karpat (Leiden: Brill, 1974), 15–34; Halil İnalcık, “Turkey Between Europe and the Middle East,” Foreign Policy 7 (1980), 12–21; Lewis H. Siegelbaum and Michael Morgan, “‘State’ versus ‘Society’ in Tsarist and Soviet History,” Radical History Review 28, no. 30 (1984), 96; Metin Heper, The State Tradition in Turkey (Walkington: Eothen Press, 1985); Binnaz Toprak, “The State, Politics, and Religion in Turkey,” in State, Democracy and the Military: Turkey in the 1980’s, eds. Metin Heper and Ahmet Evin (Berlin: Walter de Gruyter, 1988), 119–137; Ranajit Guha, Dominance Without Hegemony: History and Power in Colonial India (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1997); Susie Tharu, “Citizenship and Its Discontents,” in A Question of Silence? The Sexual Economics of Modern India, eds. Mary E. John and Janaki Nair (New Delhi: Zed Books, 1998), 224; Chitra Joshi, “Histories of Indian Labour: Predicaments and Possibilities,” History Compass 6, no. 2 (2008), 439–454.

56

Rajnarayan Chandavarkar, “’The Making of the Working Class’: E. P. Thompson and Indian History,” History Workshop Journal 43, no. 1 (1997), 179.

57

Dereli, Sendika Hareketi, 283–284; Ahmet İnsel, “Devletçiliğin Anatomisi,” in Cumhuriyet Dönemi Türkiye Ansiklopedisi 2 (Istanbul: İletişim Yayınları, 1984), 419–442; Ahmet İnsel and Cengiz Aktar, “‘Devletin Bekası’ İçin Yürütülen Çağdaşlaşma Sürecinin Toplumsal Sorunları,” Toplum ve Bilim 31, no. 39 (1987), 39; Yıldırım Koç, “1923–1950 Döneminde chp’nin İşçi Sınıfı Korkusu,” Mülkiyeliler Birliği Dergisi 170 (1994), 43–44; Yıldırım Koç, “Türkiye’de 1923–1946 Döneminde Mülksüzleşme ve İşçi Sınıfının Oluşumu,” Mülkiyeliler Birliği Dergisi 174 (1994), 14–28; M. Bülent Varlık, “Izmir Sanayi İşçileri Birliği-1932,” Mülkiyeliler Birliği Dergisi 155 (1995), 35–40; M. Bülent Varlık, “Izmir İşçi-Esnaf Kurumlar Birliği Yardım Talimatnameleri (1935–1936),” Kebikeç-İnsan Bilimleri İçin Kaynak Dergisi 4 (1996), 195–201; M. Bülent Varlık, “Izmir İşçi ve Esnaf Birlikleri Genel Bürosu Nizamnamesi (1935),” Kebikeç-İnsan Bilimleri İçin Kaynak Dergisi 5 (1997), 201–205; M. Şehmuz Güzel, Türkiye’de İşçi Hareketleri 1908–1984, (Istanbul: Kaynak Yayınları, 1996), 136–137; Hakkı Uyar, “chp Izmir İşçi ve Esnaf Cemiyetleri Birliği (1935)/Devletin İşçi Sınıfı ve Örgütlenme Girişimi,” Tarih ve Toplum 160 (1997), 14–20; Makal, “Sanayileşme Sürecinde İşgücü Sorunu ve Sosyal Politika,” 44.

58

A new wave of research decentres the state in labour history, but still, most of it refers mainly to the working-class experience outside the workplace: See, for example: Catherine Alexander, Personal States: Making Connections between People and Bureaucracy in Turkey (New York: Oxford University Press, 2002); Can Nacar, “‘Our Lives Were Not as Valuable as an Animal’: Workers in State-Run Industries in World-War-ii Turkey,” International Review of Social History 54 (2009), 143–166; Nurşen Gürboğa, “Compulsory Mine Work: The Single-Party Regime and the Zonguldak Coalfield as a Site of Contention, 1940–1947,” International Review of Social History 54 (2009), 115–142; Yiğit Akın, “The Dynamics of Working-Class Politics in Early Republican Turkey: Language, Identity, and Experience,” International Review of Social History irsh 54 (2009), 167–188; Caroline E. Arnold, “In the Service of Industrialization: Etatism, Social Services and the Construction of Industrial Labour Forces in Turkey (1930–50),” Middle Eastern Studies 48, no. 3 (2012), 363–385; Barış Alp Özden, “Health, Morality and Housing: The Politics of Working Class Housing in Turkey, 1945–1960,” New Perspectives on Turkey 49 (2013), 91–120; Ali Sipahi, “Convict Labour in Turkey, 1936–1953: A Capitalist Corporation in the State?,” International Labour and Working-Class History 90 (2016), 244–265.

59

Anna Sailer, Workplace Relations in Colonial Bengal: The Jute Industry and Indian Labour 1870s-1930s (London: Bloomsbury, 2022), 9; Paul Thompson and Chris Smith, “Labour Power and Labour Process: Contesting the Marginality of the Sociology of Work,” Sociology 43, no. 5 (2009), 916; Richard Coopey and Alan McKinlay, “Power Without Knowledge? Foucault and Fordism, c. 1900–50,” Labor History 51 (2010), 114.

60

Elton Mayo, The Human Problems of an Industrial Civilization (New York: MacMillan, 1933); Mass Observation, War Factory (MO: London, 1943); Elton Mayo, The Social Problems of an Industrial Civilization (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1949); Eric Batstone, Ian Boraston, and Stephen Frenkel, Shop Stewards in Action: The Organization of Workplace Conflict and Accommodation (Oxford: Blackwell, 1979); Carol S. Holzberg and Maureen J. Giovannini, “Anthropology and Industry: Reappraisal and New Directions,” Annual Review of Anthropology 10, no. 1 (1981), 317–360; Sheila Cunnison, “The Manchester Factory Studies, the Social Context, Bureaucratic Organisation, Sexual Divisions and Their Influence on Patterns of Accommodation between Workers and Management,” in Custom and Conflict in British Society, ed. R. Frankenberg (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1982), 94–139; Isabel Emmett and d.h.j. Morgan, “Max Gluckman and the Manchester Shop-floor Ethnographies,” in Custom and Conflict in British Society, ed. R. Frankenberg (Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1982), 140–165.

61

Mario Tronti, “Factory and Society,” trans. Guio Jacintoh, Operaismo in English, accessed 17 January 2022, https://operaismoinenglish.wordpress.com/2013/06/13/factory-and-society/.

62

Michael Burawoy, Manufacturing Consent: Changes in the Labour Process Under Monopoly Capitalism (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1979); The Politics of Production: Factory Regimes Under Capitalism and Socialism (London: Verso, 1985); P.K. Edwards,“Understanding Conflict in the Labour Process: The Logic and Autonomy of Struggle,” in Labour Process Theory, eds. D. Knight & H. Willmott (London: Palgrave Macmillan, 1990), 125–152.

63

David Montgomery, The Fall of the House of Labor: The Workplace, the State, and American Labour Activism, 1865–1925 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1987); David Brody, “Labor History in the 1970s,” in The Past Before Us: Contemporary Historical Writings in The United, ed. Michael Kammen (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1980), 252–269; Jeremy Brecher, “Uncovering the Hidden History of the American Workplace,” Review of Radical Political Economics 10, no. 4 (1978), 20; Richard Price, “’What’s in a Name?’ Workplace History and ‘Rank and Filism’,” International Review of Social History 34, no. 1 (1989), 64.

64

Peter Winn, Weavers of the Revolution: The Yarur Workers and Chile’s Road to Socialism (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1986); Diane Lauren Wolf, Factory Daughters: Gender, Household Dynamics, and Rural Industrialization in Java (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992); Kevin Yelvington, Producing Power: Ethnicity, Gender, and Class in a Caribbean Workplace (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1996); Thomas Miller Klubock, Contested Communities: Class, Gender, and Politics in Chile’s El Teniente Copper Mine, 1904–1951 (Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 1998); Angela Vergara, Copper Workers, International Business, and Domestic Politics in Cold War Chile (University Park, PA: Pennsylvania State University Press, 2008); Samer S. Shehata, Shop Floor Culture and Politics in Egypt (Albany: suny Press, 2009); Victoria Basualdo, “Shop-Floor Labour Organization in Argentina From Early Peronism to the ‘Proceso’ Military Dictatorship,” Working USA: The Journal of Labour and Society 14, no. 3 (2011), 305–332; Sailer, Workplace Relations; Hanan Hammad, Industrial Sexuality: Gender, Urbanization, and Social Transformation in Egypt (Austin: University of Texas Press, 2016); Prerna Agarwal, “The War at The Workplace: Calcutta’s Dockworkers and Changing Labour Regime, 1939–1945,” International Review of Social History 67, no. 3 (2022). A new generation of researchers revitalised the study of the socialist industrial workplace, which was previously limited to a predictably ‘party’ and teleological frame, by addressing a multitude of previously neglected questions. See: Renata Kirin and Marina Blagaić, “The Ambivalence of Socialist Working Women’s Heritage: A Case Study of the Jugoplastika Factory,” Narodna Umjetnost 1, no. 150 (2013), 40–73; Rory Archer and Goran Musić, “Approaching the Socialist Factory and Its Workforce: Considerations from Fieldwork in (Former) Yugoslavia,” Labor History 58, no. 1 (2017), 44–66; Cucu, Planning Labour; Goran Musić, Making and Breaking the Yugoslav Working Class: The Story of Two Self-Managed Factories (Budapest: Central European University Press, 2021).

65

Geert De Neve, “Towards an Ethnography of the Workplace: Hierarchy, Authority and Sociability on the South Indian Textile Shop Floor,” South Asia Research 21, no. 2 (2001), 133–160; Massimiliano Mollona, “Factory, Family and Neighbourhood: The Political Economy of Informal Labour in Sheffield,” The Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute 11, no. 3 (2005), 527–548; Jonathan Parry, Sex, Bricks and Mortar: Constructing Class in a Central Indian Steel Town,” Modern Asian Studies 48, no. 5 (2014), 1,242–1,275; Dimitra Kofti, “Moral Economy of Flexible Production: Fabricating Precarity Between the Conveyor Belt and the Household,” Anthropological Theory 16, no. 4 (2016), 433–453; Christian Strümpell, “The Anthropology of Work and Labour,” Ethnoscripts 19, no. 2 (2017), 5–14.

66

Stephen Mihm, “Interchange: The History of Capitalism,” Journal of American History 101 (2014), 504.

67

Christian G. De Vito and Anne Gerritsen, “Introduction,” in Micro-Spatial Histories of Global Labour, eds. Christian G. De Vito and Anne Gerritsen (London: Palgrave Macmillan, 2018), 1–28, 7.

68

Interview with Carlo Ginzburg by Nicolas Weill, accessed 28 February 2023, https://www.versobooks.com/blogs/5536-carlo-ginzburg-in-history-as-in-cinema-every-close-up-implies-an-off-screen-scene.

  • Collapse
  • Expand